11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

34 The <strong>Life</strong>-Cycle <strong>Hypothesis</strong><br />

Unfortunately, the variable yi e is usually unknown. Some information on it<br />

might be gathered by appropriate questions analogous to the question on shortterm<br />

in<strong>com</strong>e expectations which has already been asked in the past. Klein himself,<br />

however, has not made use <strong>of</strong> this possible source <strong>of</strong> information in the study in<br />

progress. We must, therefore, find some way <strong>of</strong> relating yi<br />

e to the variables<br />

actually used by Klein, which are also those most <strong>com</strong>monly available.<br />

It is clear that y e must bear a fairly close and reasonably stable relation to<br />

current in<strong>com</strong>e, y. In fact, at various points in the text we have suggested that the<br />

relation between these two variables maybe expressed by the equation<br />

e<br />

e<br />

Ïy = ( 1-E) y-1<br />

+ Ey+ A+<br />

U<br />

Ì<br />

Ó = ( 1-E) ( a + b y)+ Ey + U¢<br />

,<br />

(A.2)<br />

where A is a constant for a given sample (though subject to variation over time);<br />

E is the elasticity <strong>of</strong> in<strong>com</strong>e expectations defined by equation (II.11); U and<br />

U¢ =(1 - E)e¢ +U are random errors; a, b are defined by equations (II.10¢); and<br />

e¢ is the random <strong>com</strong>ponent <strong>of</strong> that equation.<br />

If we also have information on previous year’s in<strong>com</strong>e, y -1 , we can clearly<br />

exploit this information to get a better estimate <strong>of</strong> y e -1, and (A.2) then takes the<br />

form<br />

y e = a* + b y + b y + U* .<br />

1 2 -1<br />

(A.3)<br />

The coefficients <strong>of</strong> this equation, as well as the random <strong>com</strong>ponent U*, depend<br />

again on the short-term variability <strong>of</strong> in<strong>com</strong>e as measured by the correlation<br />

r yy-1 , on the variance <strong>of</strong> U and on the elasticity <strong>of</strong> expectations E. It is not<br />

worth-while, however, to derive here this relation explicitly.<br />

Substituting for y e from (A.3) into (A.1), and rearranging terms (and neglecting<br />

the error term which is proportional to U*) we get:<br />

Ï ( N - ti)<br />

a*<br />

( L-<br />

ti) ( L-<br />

Nb )-L( N -ti)<br />

b<br />

si<br />

=- +<br />

Ô Li<br />

LLi<br />

Ì<br />

( N - ti)<br />

b2<br />

Mb1<br />

( yi<br />

- y i)+<br />

L<br />

LL ty i i<br />

ÓÔ -1<br />

.<br />

i<br />

i<br />

1 2<br />

y<br />

i<br />

ai<br />

- +<br />

L<br />

i<br />

(A.4)<br />

Finally, dividing through by y i and making use <strong>of</strong> the identity L ∫ M + N, we<br />

obtain the result 62<br />

Ï si<br />

Ô yi<br />

Ì<br />

Ô<br />

Ó<br />

( Li<br />

-1)( L-<br />

Nb1)-L( Li<br />

-M-1)<br />

b2<br />

( Li<br />

-M-1)<br />

a*<br />

1 1 ai<br />

=<br />

-<br />

-<br />

LLi<br />

Li yi Li<br />

yi<br />

( N - ti)<br />

b2<br />

Mb1<br />

+ ( yi - y 1i) yi<br />

+<br />

L<br />

LL t i.<br />

Ô<br />

-<br />

i<br />

i<br />

(A.5)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!