11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

36 The <strong>Life</strong>-Cycle <strong>Hypothesis</strong><br />

basis <strong>of</strong> an analysis <strong>of</strong> factors controlling these coefficients we suggest, however,<br />

that a value in the order <strong>of</strong> .5 to .6 for b 1 and <strong>of</strong> .2 and .3 for b 2 , is not likely to<br />

be far from the mark. Using our standard assumption as to the value <strong>of</strong> L and N,<br />

we then get the following <strong>com</strong>parison:<br />

Our Model<br />

Coefficient <strong>of</strong> Klein’s estimates 64 (linear approximation)<br />

Assets -.21; -.25 -.04 to -.03<br />

In<strong>com</strong>e (.02) (.03)<br />

In<strong>com</strong>e change .03; .07 .1 to .2<br />

(.05) (.06)<br />

Age .0013; .0055 .003 to .0045<br />

(.0022) (.0024)<br />

The age coefficient falls squarely within the range <strong>of</strong> Klein’s results and<br />

nothing further need be said about it. The coefficient <strong>of</strong> in<strong>com</strong>e change estimated<br />

from the sample is lower than we should have expected, although, at least in one<br />

case, the difference from our estimate is well within the range <strong>of</strong> the standard<br />

error. 65 In the case <strong>of</strong> assets, however, the statistical coefficient is clearly far too<br />

great. A large part <strong>of</strong> this disparity is due, we suggest, to the fact that Klein’s variable<br />

L represents liquid assets whereas our variable a represents net worth, which<br />

is clearly, on the average, several times as large as liquid assets. Hence, if liquid<br />

assets holdings are a reasonably good index <strong>of</strong> total net worth, Klein’s coefficient<br />

would have to be a large multiple <strong>of</strong> ours. 66 While it is doubtful that this multiple<br />

could be as large as 6 or 7, there seems little doubt that this correction would<br />

cut the excess <strong>of</strong> Klein’s coefficient over the theoretical value very substantially,<br />

probably to well within one half. 67<br />

Unfortunately, no definite statement can be made about the coefficient <strong>of</strong><br />

in<strong>com</strong>e and the constant term on account <strong>of</strong> the logarithmic transformation introduced<br />

by Klein. However, approximate <strong>com</strong>putations we have made suggest that<br />

these coefficients are in line with our theory in the case <strong>of</strong> his first equation and<br />

somewhat too large (in absolute terms) for the second.<br />

It would thus appear that, at least in terms <strong>of</strong> orders <strong>of</strong> magnitude, Klein’s findings<br />

agree with the implications <strong>of</strong> our model. We hasten to repeat that the <strong>com</strong>parison<br />

has very limited significance and its results must be taken with a good<br />

deal <strong>of</strong> salt; yet Klein’s estimates, just as the many other empirical data we have<br />

been able to locate, would seem to warrant the feeling that we are on the right<br />

track.<br />

Notes<br />

1. John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory <strong>of</strong> Employment, Interest, and Money, 1936, p. 96.<br />

2. For two excellent bibliographies in this field, see: G. H. Orcutt and A. D. Roy, “A Bibliography<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Consumption Function,” University <strong>of</strong> Cambridge, Department <strong>of</strong> Applied Economics, mimeo-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!