11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Long-Run Implications <strong>of</strong> Alternative Fiscal Policies 81<br />

(1) Individuals or sub-groups within an economic system can, by means <strong>of</strong><br />

borrowing, increase the current flow <strong>of</strong> goods available to them and pay for this<br />

increase out <strong>of</strong> future output. But they can do so only because their borrowing is<br />

“external,” i.e., matched by a lender who yields current goods in exchange for<br />

later output. But a closed <strong>com</strong>munity cannot dispose <strong>of</strong> more goods and services<br />

than it is currently producing. It certainly cannot increase this flow by paying<br />

with future output, for there is no way “we can dispose to-day <strong>of</strong> to-morrow’s<br />

output.” Hence the goods and services acquired by the government must always<br />

be “paid for” by those present at the time in the form <strong>of</strong> a reduction in the flow<br />

<strong>of</strong> goods available to them for private use, and cannot possibly be paid for by<br />

later generations, whether the acquisition is financed by taxes or by internal borrowing.<br />

Only through external borrowing is it possible to benefit the current generation<br />

and to impose a burden on the future.<br />

(2) Although internal borrowing will leave in its wake an obligation for future<br />

tax-payers to pay the interest on the national debt and, possibly, to repay the principal,<br />

this obligation is not a net burden on the <strong>com</strong>munity as a whole, because<br />

these payments are but transfers <strong>of</strong> in<strong>com</strong>e between future members <strong>of</strong> the <strong>com</strong>munity.<br />

The loss <strong>of</strong> the tax-payers is <strong>of</strong>fset in the aggregate by the gain <strong>of</strong> the<br />

beneficiary <strong>of</strong> the payment. These transfers may, <strong>of</strong> course, occur between people<br />

<strong>of</strong> different ages and hence <strong>of</strong> different “generations,” and in this sense internal<br />

borrowing may cause “intergenerations transfers,” but it will not cause a net loss<br />

to society.<br />

The above two arguments, or some reasonable variant there<strong>of</strong>, have provided<br />

the cornerstone <strong>of</strong> the no-transfer, no-burden argument over the last two centuries<br />

or so. It was left for Keynesian analysis to provide a third argument, removing<br />

thereby a potentially troublesome objection to the first two. If the cost <strong>of</strong> government<br />

expenditure always falls on the current generation, no matter how<br />

financed, why not forego altogether the painful activity <strong>of</strong> levying taxes? Yet our<br />

<strong>com</strong>mon sense rebels at this conclusion. A partial answer to this puzzle was provided<br />

by recognising that taxes, even when paid back in the form <strong>of</strong> transfers,<br />

generate some “frictional loss,” because most if not all feasible methods <strong>of</strong> raising<br />

tax revenue tend to interfere with the optimum allocation <strong>of</strong> resources. 7 Presumably<br />

the ever-increasing level <strong>of</strong> the national debt resulting from full deficit<br />

financing <strong>of</strong> current expenditure would require raising through taxes an evergrowing<br />

revenue to pay the interest on the debt. Eventually the ratio <strong>of</strong> such taxes<br />

to national in<strong>com</strong>e plus transfers would exceed the ratio <strong>of</strong> government expenditure<br />

to national product, giving rise to frictional tax losses which could have<br />

been avoided through a balanced budget. While these considerations do provide<br />

a prima facie case for a balanced-budget policy, the case is not tight, for could<br />

not the interest itself be met by further borrowing?

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!