17.05.2015 Views

14-1190b-innovation-managing-risk-evidence

14-1190b-innovation-managing-risk-evidence

14-1190b-innovation-managing-risk-evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

156<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Chapter 1: Innovation, Risk and Government:<br />

Perspectives and principles from the social<br />

sciences<br />

A full bibliography can be found at the end of<br />

the reference list for this chapter.<br />

1. The authors would like to warmly thank<br />

Nick Crafts, David Newbery and John<br />

Vickers for their thoughtful comments and<br />

guidance. We have also benefited greatly<br />

from discussions with Tim Besley, Stefan<br />

Heck, Mark Schankerman and Cathy Zoi, and<br />

with the other contributing authors to this<br />

volume. We are grateful to the Grantham<br />

Research Institute on Climate Change & the<br />

Environment at the LSE for their support<br />

in producing this chapter. Any errors or<br />

omissions are our own.<br />

2. See Perez (2010) and Stoneman (1995).<br />

3. Hall & Rosenberg (2010) and Balconi et al.<br />

(2010).<br />

4. In addition, <strong>innovation</strong> applies to the<br />

understanding of <strong>innovation</strong> itself — and a host<br />

of other social processes and policy problems.<br />

Hall & Rosenberg (2010) point out “the topic<br />

of <strong>innovation</strong> systems and institutions is still in<br />

its infancy empirically”. Gallagher et al. (2012)<br />

point out that we need better measurement,<br />

modelling and theorising about <strong>innovation</strong>.<br />

This will allow better policy design, and a<br />

more powerful <strong>innovation</strong> system, in the<br />

future.<br />

5. Department for Business, Innovation & Skills<br />

(20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

6. Crafts & O’Rourke (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

7. Crafts & O’Rourke (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

8. Christensen (1997).<br />

9. In some cases, such as those of displaced<br />

workers, those who lose may deserve<br />

supportive policies; in other cases, like that<br />

of firms in a competitive market, the threat<br />

of being a loser is often what spurs further<br />

<strong>innovation</strong>.<br />

10. Sometimes strong stimulus for <strong>innovation</strong><br />

comes from threat and war, but not all<br />

resulting <strong>innovation</strong>s enhance human wellbeing.<br />

11. Perez (2010).<br />

12. Solow (1956); Swan (1956).<br />

13. See, e.g., European Commission (2001), 5, 11.<br />

Innovations increase productivity by using<br />

existing resources in new or more productive<br />

ways.<br />

<strong>14</strong>. Galasso & Schankerman (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

15. Hall & Rosenberg 2010 p5.<br />

16. Other market failures that may be relevant to<br />

the incentives for <strong>innovation</strong> in certain sectors<br />

(e.g. the energy sector) include network<br />

infrastructure, coordination problems and<br />

inadequate information.<br />

17. Griliches (1992); Hall et al. (2009); Griffith et<br />

al. (2004).<br />

18. Galasso & Schankerman (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

19. Jaffe, et al. (2005).<br />

20. For example, the political literacy and<br />

enculturation that results in stable institutions<br />

and a healthy society: see, e.g. Friedman (1962).<br />

21. E.g. see Moretti (2004) Lange and Topel (2006).<br />

22. Gallagher et al. (2012).<br />

23. Stern (1989) provides a list of reasons why<br />

government interventions can fail (at p. 616).<br />

24. Winston (2006).<br />

25. This concept draws on work of Schumpeter<br />

(1934) and later ‘evolutionary’ theorists of<br />

<strong>innovation</strong> (e.g. Nelson and Winter 1982).<br />

26. Freeman (1995); Lundvall (2010).<br />

27. Crafts & Hughes (2013). For example,<br />

numerous authors conceive of the state<br />

playing a role within <strong>innovation</strong> systems<br />

beyond merely fixing market failures and<br />

“facilitating” private sector <strong>innovation</strong>: see,<br />

e.g., Johnson (1982); Chang (2008); Mazzucato<br />

(2013).<br />

28. E.g. see Lundvall (2007); Dasgupta & David<br />

(1994).<br />

29. See Knight (1921).<br />

30. The Tick-Tock model is a chip technology<br />

roadmap, where every 12-18 months either<br />

a “tick” or “tock” is expected. A “tick”<br />

represents a shrinking of transistor size, and<br />

a “tock” represents a new microarchitecture<br />

taking advantage of that smaller size. This<br />

relative predictability is marketed to investors<br />

as an attractive feature of Intel’s model. http://<br />

www.intel.com/content/www/us/en/silicon<strong>innovation</strong>s/intel-tick-tock-model-general.html.<br />

31. Gallagher et al. (2012).<br />

32. See Grossman and Helpman (1991); Lipsey et<br />

al. (2005); Ruttan (2006).<br />

33. Cohen (2010).<br />

34. Cohen (2010). Though of course, in the ICT<br />

sector, there are many large firms as well, such<br />

as Google, Apple, Microsoft and Facebook.<br />

35. Cohen (2010); Schumpeter (1934).<br />

36. Network linkages between firms and public<br />

sector agencies (e.g. universities) are also<br />

important and are discussed in the following<br />

section on firms and other institutions.<br />

37. Schilling and Phelps (2007); Nooteboom<br />

(1999).<br />

38. Coe and Helpman (1995).<br />

39. LSE Growth Commission (2013).<br />

40. Mazzucato (2013). Nicholas Stern was<br />

directly involved as Chief Economist in the<br />

1990s building principles and strategies for<br />

the investments of the EBRD, on the board<br />

preparing for the UK’s Green Investment<br />

Bank, as Chief Economist of the World Bank<br />

(2000-2003), and in the design and launch<br />

of the new BRICS-led development bank<br />

(announced on 15/7/20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

41. Cohen (2010).<br />

42. Cohen (2010).<br />

43. Bloom and Van Reenen (2006).<br />

44. i.e. innovators are unable to capture the full<br />

returns from their <strong>innovation</strong>.<br />

45. Baumol (2002).<br />

46. Galasso & Schankerman (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

47. When patents are annulled, small firm<br />

<strong>innovation</strong> increases by a remarkable 520% on<br />

average: Galasso & Schankerman (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

48. Foray and Lissoni (2010).<br />

49. Many studies find that the co-location of<br />

start-ups and universities has little effect upon<br />

<strong>innovation</strong> or the strength of cross-sectoral<br />

relationships: see Foray & Lissoni (2010) pp.<br />

303-305 and references there cited.<br />

50. Foray & Lissoni (2010)<br />

51. Azoulay et al. (2011); Editor (2009).<br />

52. Azoulay et al. (2011).<br />

53. E.g. see Etzkowitz, H. (2003).<br />

54. See Foray & Lissoni (2010); Agrawal and<br />

Henderson (2002).<br />

55. Dasgupta & David (1994)<br />

56. Foray & Lissoni (2010); Philpott et al. (2011).<br />

57. See Higgs (2013); Zimmer, M. (2009). GFP:<br />

from jellyfish to the Nobel prize and beyond.<br />

Chemical Society Reviews, 38(10), 2823-2832;<br />

and Azoulay et al. (2011).<br />

58. Kahneman & Tversky (1979).<br />

59. Chen and Miller (2007); Chen (2008).<br />

60. IEA (20<strong>14</strong>), Data Services Table. See public<br />

energy R&D spending from 1970s to<br />

the present day. http://wds.iea.org/WDS/<br />

TableViewer/tableView.aspx.<br />

61. This debate is framed as intrinsic motivation/<br />

extrinsic incentive in behavioural economics<br />

(e.g. see work by Swiss economist, Bruno Frey<br />

(1994 and 1997) on how intrinsic motivation<br />

can be crowded out by extrinsic incentives).<br />

Or for example, using financial incentives to<br />

improve teacher and student outcomes—<br />

one prerequisite for an effective <strong>innovation</strong><br />

system—can actually harm educational<br />

outcomes. E.g. Fryer (2010 and 2011).<br />

62. E.g. on soft vs. hard institutions see: Klein<br />

Woolthuis et al. (2005); Lundvall (2010).<br />

63. See, e.g., Kahneman (2011); Thaler and<br />

Sunstein (2008); Mullainathan and Shafir<br />

(2013).<br />

64. Johnson and Goldstein (2004).<br />

65. E.g. see Behavioural Insight Team (2012) Paper<br />

on Fraud, Error and Debt; Wenzel (2004).<br />

66. Camerer et al. (2003).<br />

67. Haynes et al. (2012).<br />

68. As countries “approach the frontier” of<br />

<strong>innovation</strong>, it “becomes more important<br />

to have high-quality education”: Crafts &<br />

O’Rourke (20<strong>14</strong>).<br />

69. See the above discussion on patents in section<br />

B(ii).<br />

70. Smits and Kuhlmann (2004).<br />

71. Azoulay, Graff Zivin and Manso (2011); Editor<br />

(2009). Further, we note that principal/<br />

agent issues would be relevant to how much<br />

freedom is needed to foster <strong>innovation</strong> and<br />

how such a system would be managed. At the<br />

same time, it would be beneficial to find the<br />

right balance between the micro-management<br />

of innovators and total freedom.<br />

72. Griliches (1992); Hall et al. (2009); Griffith et<br />

al. (2004).<br />

73. European Council for Nuclear Research, see<br />

http://home.web.cern.ch/.<br />

74. Mazzucato 2013.<br />

75. Abbate (1999); National Research Council<br />

[US] (1999); Mazzucato (2013).<br />

76. Motoyama et al. (2011). The US Government<br />

currently spends $1.8 billion across 13 state<br />

agencies on the National Nanotechnology<br />

Initiative: Mazzucato (2013); http://

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!