17.05.2015 Views

14-1190b-innovation-managing-risk-evidence

14-1190b-innovation-managing-risk-evidence

14-1190b-innovation-managing-risk-evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

16<br />

Investors face additional <strong>risk</strong>s when investing in a variety<br />

of new situations — e.g. new technologies, new policy<br />

environments. Some of these <strong>risk</strong>s can be mitigated by<br />

policy (see Part B), but the nature of capital markets,<br />

in which lenders also have to be persuaded of the yet<br />

undemonstrated prospects, mean it is impossible to cover<br />

them all.<br />

• Behaviour different from that embodied in the<br />

standard “rational” representation of individuals in<br />

economic models can limit <strong>innovation</strong>. Our tendency<br />

to focus on the short-term, to dislike <strong>risk</strong> and uncertainty,<br />

and to stick with the status quo can lead to “<strong>innovation</strong><br />

neglect” in public and private institutions alike (see Part B).<br />

• The development of human capital and associated<br />

markets is restricted by its own spillovers. The<br />

education of individuals provides social benefits, by<br />

providing human capital upon which public and private<br />

sectors, and society as a whole 20 , can draw. These benefits<br />

are not fully captured by the educated individual, or by<br />

schools or firms that may educate that individual, so<br />

markets tend to provide less education than is socially<br />

efficient 21 .<br />

• Sustained support for incumbent technologies.<br />

Most energy sectors, for instance, have been historically<br />

designed for fossil fuel use, thus development of low-/<br />

zero-carbon sources of energy may be slowed and many<br />

aspects of the energy system may need to change in<br />

addition to the sources. Existing institutions, infrastructure<br />

and policies that support certain sectors, can result in<br />

sector inertia that provides “barriers to entry for new<br />

technologies” 22 .<br />

It is not just markets that fail. Governments, with good<br />

intentions or otherwise, having different competencies and<br />

facing diverse pressures, can also fail. Attempts to pick<br />

winners sometimes lead to second-guessing markets and<br />

wasted resources 23 . A poorly designed policy, or one that<br />

does not carry credibility, can present a greater threat to<br />

<strong>innovation</strong> than the market failures it was supposed to<br />

resolve 24 . Reasons for government failure include:<br />

• asymmetric information;<br />

• lack of experience or competence in business or science;<br />

• rent-seeking or lobbying by private actors;<br />

• short-term time horizons driven by electoral cycles.<br />

The ‘systems of <strong>innovation</strong>’ approach focuses on how<br />

firms of different types, government actors and other<br />

economic agents, are embedded in ‘systems of <strong>innovation</strong>’<br />

(sectoral, regional, national), or ‘<strong>innovation</strong> ecosystems’ 25 .<br />

The approach emphasizes the importance of interactions<br />

between actors in such systems (which are often non-linear,<br />

involving important feedback loops), and how knowledge is<br />

diffused throughout the economy 26 . In distinction from the<br />

‘market failures’ approach, the <strong>innovation</strong> systems literature<br />

focuses on the importance of both market and non-market<br />

actors, relationships and norms in determining <strong>innovation</strong><br />

behaviour. This expands the possible scope of useful state<br />

intervention 27 , but at the same time provides further<br />

possible sources of government failure. Poor government<br />

policy may, for example, override existing norms (such as<br />

those for openness among academic researchers) and result<br />

in unexpected negative effects on <strong>innovation</strong> 28 .<br />

Both frameworks bring valuable insights to our<br />

understanding of <strong>innovation</strong> and how it can be fostered<br />

to promote growth. From here on, we focus more on the<br />

market failure framework because it has a longer-standing<br />

literature, but we draw on both.<br />

(iii) Innovation, <strong>risk</strong>s and incentives<br />

There is significant potential for policy to boost <strong>innovation</strong>,<br />

and thereby boost economic growth. To design policy<br />

that effectively and efficiently fosters <strong>innovation</strong>, we must<br />

understand how actors along the <strong>innovation</strong> chain respond<br />

to the <strong>risk</strong>s and incentives they face.<br />

“Risk” and “uncertainty” in economic analyses are often<br />

used interchangeably but the American economist Frank<br />

Knight distinguished them along the following lines 29 :<br />

• “Risk” can be thought of as measurable and<br />

quantifiable in terms of probabilities, and is<br />

most useful for describing investment in predictable<br />

advances further along the <strong>innovation</strong> chain. Intel’s<br />

investments in chip technology, for example, produce<br />

incremental improvements that are predicted years in<br />

advance according to Intel’s “tick-tock” model of chip<br />

improvement 30 , where improvements are reliable enough<br />

that the metaphor of a clock fits.<br />

• “Uncertainty” can be thought of as that which is<br />

not easily measurable in terms of probabilities, where<br />

we may even be unsure of what possibilities exist. This<br />

can be the case in complex, chaotic systems composed<br />

of many interacting elements — and along the <strong>innovation</strong><br />

chain, “all of the actors operate under conditions of<br />

uncertainty” 31 . This applies especially in early phases of the<br />

chain, and in <strong>innovation</strong> over the long term. Policymakers<br />

could not have foreseen that studying jellyfish would<br />

found a large part of the biomedical revolution, or that<br />

military packet switching technologies intended to make<br />

military communication systems more resilient in the<br />

event of a nuclear attack would lead to the internet, social<br />

networking and the avalanche of apps spawned in Silicon<br />

Valley.<br />

Private actors face a diversity of <strong>risk</strong>s — financial <strong>risk</strong>s,<br />

career <strong>risk</strong>s, legal <strong>risk</strong>s, and many beyond — when they<br />

choose to innovate. The balance of <strong>risk</strong>s and incentives<br />

determines what choices innovators (entrepreneurs,<br />

investors, inventors, bureaucrats, etc.) will make.<br />

Being exposed to <strong>risk</strong> is part of doing business. But some<br />

<strong>risk</strong>s are appropriate guides to decision-making, while others<br />

may be unhelpfully imposed. Deciding not to proceed with<br />

an <strong>innovation</strong> investment because there is a high <strong>risk</strong> of<br />

insufficient demand is a sensible decision — the kind of<br />

decision that firms make routinely in order to maximize<br />

their value. Deciding not to proceed with a very promising<br />

<strong>innovation</strong> because of the <strong>risk</strong>s imposed by regulatory<br />

unpredictability (e.g. policy <strong>risk</strong>), lack of appropriability (e.g.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!