10.07.2015 Views

Growing the Wealth of the Poor - World Resources Institute

Growing the Wealth of the Poor - World Resources Institute

Growing the Wealth of the Poor - World Resources Institute

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

OWNERSHIP54W O R L D R E S O U R C E S 2 0 0 8FIGURE 2 GROWTH IN COMMUNITY FORESTOWNERSHIP WORLDWIDE, 1985-2002Communally owned forest area(million hectares)40030020010001985 2002Source: White and Martin 2002: 11<strong>of</strong> its degraded state forestlands to communities, and <strong>the</strong> head <strong>of</strong>China’s State Forest Administration said that streng<strong>the</strong>ning localproperty rights was a top priority (White et al. 2007:15; White andMartin 2002:4-7; Lok Sabha 2006).How this will play out in terms <strong>of</strong> actual increases in forestbasedenterprises is again unknown. There is <strong>of</strong>ten a significantdifference between policy and practice on <strong>the</strong> ground, and <strong>the</strong>nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tenure rights granted to communities varies widely,from substantive to shallow. In addition, <strong>the</strong>re are many requirementsfor successful enterprise beyond resource access.None<strong>the</strong>less, current trends show that governments are increasinglyaware that ecosystem resources have considerable potentialto contribute to rural development if progress on <strong>the</strong> issue <strong>of</strong>resource tenure can be made (White et al. 2007:15).Local Demand and CommitmentSuccessful ecosystem-based enterprises arise out <strong>of</strong> an expresseddemand from <strong>the</strong> community. Secure resource rights alone arenot sufficient. There must be <strong>the</strong> desire and willingness to use<strong>the</strong>se rights to jointly manage ecosystems, reflecting <strong>the</strong> beliefthat doing so will benefit individuals and <strong>the</strong> group. (See Box 2.2.)Demand manifests itself as community consensus on <strong>the</strong> need toact and a commitment on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> stakeholdersto adhere to an agreed action plan. Without this kind <strong>of</strong>demand from <strong>the</strong> community, ecosystem enterprises are likely t<strong>of</strong>ail; people will not maintain projects or adhere to managementplans over <strong>the</strong> long term that <strong>the</strong>y do not want or do not considerfair. Similarly, by requiring commitments and investments—<strong>of</strong>labor, money, or o<strong>the</strong>r resources—community-based enterpriseencourages a sense <strong>of</strong> local ownership, in turn engenderingsustained involvement on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> participants.Insights on <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> community demand forsuccess in development efforts first arose out <strong>of</strong> experience withwater and sanitation projects in <strong>the</strong> 1970s and 1980s. Authoritiesnoted that drinking water or sewer projects that were plannedand executed without consultation with local communities <strong>of</strong>tenfailed to meet community needs and subsequently were underusedand poorly maintained. In contrast, projects that respondedto focused community demand and involved <strong>the</strong> community indesign, construction, and maintenance had a better performanceand cost-recovery record (Deverill et al. 2002:2–3; Breslin2003:1–10). These lessons provided <strong>the</strong> groundwork <strong>of</strong> experiencefor <strong>the</strong> community-driven development approach and apoint <strong>of</strong> reference for examining <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> demand.The Structure <strong>of</strong> Demand for Rural EnterpriseIn <strong>the</strong> realm <strong>of</strong> community development, demand can be definedas “an informed expression <strong>of</strong> desire for a particular service,measured by <strong>the</strong> contribution people are willing and able to maketo receive this service” (Deverill 2000:1). A “contribution” <strong>of</strong>tenincludes time and effort, not just goods and money. For naturebasedenterprises, <strong>the</strong> service involved is an ecosystem service,such as increased agricultural production, <strong>the</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> timberor non-timber forest products (NTFPs), higher fisheries production,or landscapes and species that attract tourists.Demand is not static; it develops with changes in <strong>the</strong>community and <strong>the</strong> resource base. Among some groups, demandfor jointly managing ecosystems has deep historical roots, but ithas <strong>of</strong>ten broken down as modern tenure patterns and economicforces have disrupted traditional ways. In o<strong>the</strong>r instances, degradation<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> resource base or new opportunities for resourceexploitation <strong>of</strong>fer conditions for <strong>the</strong> demand for communityresource management to arise.Development <strong>of</strong> local demand can be envisioned in threestages. First, <strong>the</strong>re is a change, or initiating event in <strong>the</strong> community.Second, participants decide whe<strong>the</strong>r or not to respond tothis change. This usually involves deliberation among <strong>the</strong>community members, with individuals weighing <strong>the</strong> costs andbenefits to <strong>the</strong>mselves. Third, <strong>the</strong> participants decide how toaddress <strong>the</strong> problem. These stages are iterative and not discretefrom one ano<strong>the</strong>r, as people constantly update <strong>the</strong>ir informationand weigh <strong>the</strong> consequences <strong>of</strong> participation or nonparticipation(White and Runge 1995:1685).The initiating event that leads to demand for a new ecosystementerprise can come from a number <strong>of</strong> sources: a change in<strong>the</strong> information available, a change in <strong>the</strong> local environment oreconomy, a change in <strong>the</strong> financial incentives for investment, ora change in resource rights or access that makes resources moreavailable. A dynamic community leader who can put <strong>the</strong> changein perspective and advocate for action is <strong>of</strong>ten an important part<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> mix. In many cases, several <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se factors work inconcert to create <strong>the</strong> perception that a new opportunity is athand. In <strong>the</strong> end, <strong>the</strong> decision whe<strong>the</strong>r to act on this opportunityis a function <strong>of</strong> available information, communitydynamics, and <strong>the</strong> perceived costs <strong>of</strong> action versus inaction(Lobo 2007; White and Runge 1995:1685).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!