12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

146Gordon H Hansonberg et al. (2008) found that lower tariffs <strong>in</strong> imported <strong>in</strong>puts led to an <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> the variety of <strong>in</strong>puts available on the Indian market, which <strong>in</strong> turn lowered effective<strong>in</strong>put prices for firms. Here aga<strong>in</strong>, the evidence on the effects of trade ismixed. Us<strong>in</strong>g data for Brazil, Muendler (2008) takes a different approach, exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gwhether plant productivity is associated with access to foreign <strong>in</strong>puts. Hefound that the effect, while present, accounts for only a small part of the posttrade reform growth <strong>in</strong> Brazilian productivity.Increased trade <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts has other important effects on <strong>in</strong>dustrialstructure. Input trade arises <strong>in</strong> part because of global production networks, <strong>in</strong>which mult<strong>in</strong>ational firms divide the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>in</strong>to stages and locateeach stage <strong>in</strong> the country where it can be performed at least cost (Feenstraand Hanson, 2003). The expansion of US owned maquiladoras (export assemblyplants) <strong>in</strong> Mexico (Feenstra and Hanson, 1997), Hong Kong export process<strong>in</strong>gestablishments <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a (Hsieh and Woo, 2005), Japanese assembly plants <strong>in</strong>Southeast Asia (Head and Ries, 2002), and European subcontractors <strong>in</strong> EasternEurope (Mar<strong>in</strong>, 2008) are all examples of the global fragmentation of manufactur<strong>in</strong>g.Skill and capital <strong>in</strong>tensive stages of production rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> high wage countries,while labor-<strong>in</strong>tensive stages move to low wage countries. Global productionnetworks appear to be based on comparative advantage, but <strong>in</strong> an environmentof extreme specialization. In the HO model, extreme specialization arises onlywith the absence of factor price equalization (FPE). While the lack of FPE mayseem a natural assumption to make for the analysis of trade between developedand develop<strong>in</strong>g economies, it is only recently that trade economists have begunto apply empirically the extensions of the HO model that allow for unequal factorprices.Feenstra and Hanson (1997) provide a model of the globalization of production<strong>in</strong> which firms <strong>in</strong> a skill-abundant North use firms <strong>in</strong> a non skill-abundant Southto produce <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts. Assum<strong>in</strong>g wages differ between nations, the Northspecializes <strong>in</strong> high skill tasks and the South specializes <strong>in</strong> low skill tasks. Whilea reduction <strong>in</strong> trade barriers has effects qualitatively similar to the Stolper–Samuelson theorem, the movement of capital or the transfer of technology fromNorth to South has effects that are quite different. If Northern firms use foreigndirect <strong>in</strong>vestment to move production to the South, they will logically choose tomove the least skill-<strong>in</strong>tensive activities that they perform. By mov<strong>in</strong>g these activitiesto the South, the average skill <strong>in</strong>tensity of production rises <strong>in</strong> the North.The same also happens <strong>in</strong> the South, s<strong>in</strong>ce the South <strong>in</strong>itially specializes <strong>in</strong> theleast skilled tasks. When the North ‘offshores’ production to the South, it turnsout that the relative demand for high-skilled workers rises <strong>in</strong> both countries. Naturally,trade costs determ<strong>in</strong>e the magnitude of offshor<strong>in</strong>g from North to South.For data on US mult<strong>in</strong>ational firms, Hanson et al. (2005) found that export of <strong>in</strong>termediate<strong>in</strong>puts to their foreign affiliates for further process<strong>in</strong>g is strongly negativelycorrelated with tariffs and shipp<strong>in</strong>g costs.In the next section, I discuss the implications of offshor<strong>in</strong>g for wages. In therema<strong>in</strong>der of this section, I focus on what offshor<strong>in</strong>g means for how Northern andSouthern firms adjust to changes <strong>in</strong> macroeconomic conditions. If we assume

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!