12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

A Structural Empirical Approach to <strong>Trade</strong> Shocks and Labor <strong>Adjustment</strong> 45Table 3.2: Descriptive Statistics: Wages, 2004–6 (normalized)Agric/M<strong>in</strong> 0.5648Manuf/Const 0.9253<strong>Trade</strong>/Hotels 0.8046Service 1.18823. RESULTSBefore show<strong>in</strong>g estimations, we should po<strong>in</strong>t out that we do not attempt toestimate β. This model is not designed to estimate rates of time preference, andalthough it could be done <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, <strong>in</strong> practice it turns out that that oneparameter is very poorly identified. It turns out that estimat<strong>in</strong>g and simulat<strong>in</strong>gthe model with different values of β produces nearly identical time paths for keyobservable variables, so it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g that it is hard to identify econometrically.We simply impose a value of β <strong>in</strong> all that follows; to check for sensitivity to thechoice of β, we report estimations with both β = 0.9 and β = 0.97.Table 3.3 shows the results from the basic regression. As mentioned above, weimpose, so that the mean mov<strong>in</strong>g cost for any transition from one<strong>in</strong>dustry to any other is the same. Throughout the table, the t-statistics arereported <strong>in</strong> parentheses.Table 3.3: Regression Results for the Basic Modelβ = 0.97 β = 0.9v C v C2.56 22.89 1.62 9.50(3.50***) (3.23***) (5.36***) (5.36***)Notes: T-statistics are <strong>in</strong> parentheses; one-tailed significance: 1-percent***; 5-percent**; 10-percent*.The first two columns report results for β = 0.97, and the last two report resultsfor β = 0.9. Notice that the estimated mov<strong>in</strong>g costs are enormous. Given ourconvention on normaliz<strong>in</strong>g wages, the value of C is estimated at 9.50 and 22.88times average annual <strong>in</strong>come, for the two cases respectively. The two values forv translate to a standard deviation for the idiosyncratic shocks of just over oneyear’saverage annual earn<strong>in</strong>gs. This reflects both the modest levels of gross flowsobserved <strong>in</strong> Table 3.1 and the fact that the flows respond only modestly to wagedifferentials across sectors. This suggests that the labor market will likely besluggish <strong>in</strong> reallocat<strong>in</strong>g workers follow<strong>in</strong>g a trade shock, as will be confirmed <strong>in</strong>the simulations.Strictly speak<strong>in</strong>g, OLS is likely to be biased <strong>in</strong> this case, because the disturbanceterm, μ t+1 , conta<strong>in</strong>s any new <strong>in</strong>formation at date t+1 and so will <strong>in</strong> general becorrelated with date t+1 regressors. This implies a need for <strong>in</strong>strumental variables.The theory implies that past values of the flows and wages will be valid<strong>in</strong>struments, and the optimal weight<strong>in</strong>g scheme can be derived as <strong>in</strong> theGeneralized Method of Moments (GMM) (Hansen 1982). This strategy is employed

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!