12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

338Miet Maertens and Jo Sw<strong>in</strong>nenfirms might prefer to contract with smaller farms because they might have a costadvantage—especially if it concerns labour <strong>in</strong>tensive production—or because contractenforcement might be less costly with small suppliers.The actual evidence on smallholder <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> high-standards supplycha<strong>in</strong>s and the changes <strong>in</strong> this <strong>in</strong>duced by standards is very mixed. There arecases of complete vertical <strong>in</strong>tegration with hardly any smallholder <strong>in</strong>volvement;for example <strong>in</strong> the tomato export sector <strong>in</strong> Senegal (Maertens et al., 2008) andthe fruit and vegetable export sectors <strong>in</strong> Zambia (Legge et al., 2006). On the otherhand, there are also many examples of cases where export production—dest<strong>in</strong>edfor markets where standards are high and <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g—rema<strong>in</strong>s dom<strong>in</strong>ated bysmallholders; for example the vegetable export sector <strong>in</strong> Madagascar (M<strong>in</strong>ten etal., 2006) and Ghana (Legge et al., 2006). In most cases of high-standards exportproduction there is a mix between smallholder contract production and largescaleagro-<strong>in</strong>dustrial production (Maertens et al., 2009). Some studies havepo<strong>in</strong>ted to sharp reductions <strong>in</strong> the share of smallholder production as standards<strong>in</strong>crease; for example Jaffee (2003)—recogniz<strong>in</strong>g the limitations of the availabledata—estimates that for export vegetables <strong>in</strong> Kenya the share of smallholder productiondecreased from 45 per cent <strong>in</strong> the mid 1980s to 27 per cent <strong>in</strong> 2001–02.More recent studies, however, state that these early estimates exaggerate the problemof <strong>in</strong>creased smallholder exclusion and that <strong>in</strong> fact more smallholders are<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> Kenyan high-standards horticulture exports than previously estimated(Asfaw et al., 2007; Mithoefer et al., 2006). In general the figures on horticulturesectors <strong>in</strong> Africa seem to po<strong>in</strong>t out that there is actually much moresmallholder <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> high-standards production than would be assumedbased on the above arguments. Similar observations were described for severalagricultural sectors <strong>in</strong> transition countries <strong>in</strong> Eastern Europe and Central Asia(Sw<strong>in</strong>nen, 2005).Concern<strong>in</strong>g the issue of exploitation of smallholder producers, it has repeatedlybeen argued that the ga<strong>in</strong>s from high-standards agricultural trade are capturedby foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors, large food companies, and develop<strong>in</strong>g country elites andthat standards lead to a more unequal distribution of the ga<strong>in</strong>s from trade (for example,Dolan and Humphrey, 2000; Reardon et al., 1999). On the one hand, consolidationof the export supply base and vertical coord<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> the supply cha<strong>in</strong>sare said to amplify the barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power of large agro-<strong>in</strong>dustrial firms and foodmult<strong>in</strong>ationals, displace decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g authority from the farmers to thesedownstream companies, and strengthen the capacity of these companies to extractrents from the cha<strong>in</strong> to the disadvantage of poor farmers and local households(Warn<strong>in</strong>g and Key, 2002). On the other hand, vertical coord<strong>in</strong>ation schemesprovide a basis for farmers to access the credit, <strong>in</strong>puts, and technology they needfor upgrad<strong>in</strong>g their production <strong>in</strong> terms of productivity and quality and to <strong>in</strong>creasetheir <strong>in</strong>comes.Recent empirical studies have demonstrated a beneficial effect for smallholdersparticipat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> high-standards contract production. Demonstrated benefits <strong>in</strong>cludeproductivity ga<strong>in</strong>s, <strong>in</strong>creased household <strong>in</strong>come, reduced volatility, and more stable<strong>in</strong>comes, technology spillovers and so on. For example, Dries and Sw<strong>in</strong>nen

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!