12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Adjustment</strong> to Internal Migration 207India, the tax consequences of skilled emigration appear to be small, though smallcountries with high emigration rates may face larger impacts.In receiv<strong>in</strong>g countries, immigration may exacerbate <strong>in</strong>efficiencies associatedwith a country’s system of public f<strong>in</strong>ance. Where immigrants pay more <strong>in</strong> taxesthan they receive <strong>in</strong> government benefits, immigration reduces the net tax burdenon native taxpayers. The total impact of immigration on native residents—the sum of the immigration surplus (the pretax <strong>in</strong>come ga<strong>in</strong>) and the net fiscaltransfer from immigrants—would be positive. With progressive taxes and meanstestedentitlements <strong>in</strong> many receiv<strong>in</strong>g countries, positive fiscal consequences fromimmigration would be more likely, the more skilled is the labor <strong>in</strong>flow. In contextswhere immigrants pay less <strong>in</strong> taxes than they receive <strong>in</strong> government benefits,immigration <strong>in</strong>creases the net tax burden on natives, necessitat<strong>in</strong>g an<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> taxes on natives, a reduction <strong>in</strong> government benefits to natives, or <strong>in</strong>creasedborrow<strong>in</strong>g from future generations.There are dynamic fiscal effects from immigration (Auerbach and Oreopoulos,1999). If the net tax burden on residents of a country is expected to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>the future, immigration <strong>in</strong>creases the tax base over which the burden is spreadand reduces the <strong>in</strong>crease that natives have to bear (Collado and Valera, 2004). Butthis is only true if the descendents of immigrants make positive net tax contributions.If the children of immigrants have low educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment, high levelsof immigration today could <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>in</strong>crease the future tax burden on thenative population.In the United States, immigrant households have historically made greater useof subsidized health care, <strong>in</strong>come support to poor families, food stamps, and othertypes of public assistance (Borjas and H<strong>in</strong>ton, 1996). The reason for native–immigrantdifferences <strong>in</strong> the uptake of welfare programs is simple. Immigranthouseholds tend to be larger than native households; they have more children,and have very low <strong>in</strong>comes, mak<strong>in</strong>g them eligible for more types of benefits. Inthe last decade, however, the difference between immigrant and native use ofwelfare programs <strong>in</strong> the United States has fallen because of reforms to welfarepolicy, which restricted non-citizens from hav<strong>in</strong>g access to many federally fundedbenefit programs. While immigrant households still make greater use of publichealthcare than native households do, their use of other types of public assistancehas fallen (Borjas, 2003; Capps et al., 2005). In the European Union, enlargementto <strong>in</strong>clude lower <strong>in</strong>come countries <strong>in</strong> Central and Eastern Europe haslead to low-skilled migration to higher <strong>in</strong>come countries, possibly <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g welfareusage (S<strong>in</strong>n, 2002).Calculat<strong>in</strong>g the total fiscal consequences of immigration, while straightforwardconceptually, is difficult <strong>in</strong> practice. To estimate them correctly, one needs toknow many details about the <strong>in</strong>come, spend<strong>in</strong>g, and employment behavior of thepopulation of immigrants. As a result, there are few comprehensive national levelanalyses of the fiscal impact of immigration. In one of the few such studies, Smithand Edmonston (1997) estimate that <strong>in</strong> 1996 immigration imposed a short-run fiscalburden on the average US native household of $200, or 0.2 percent of USGDP. In that year, a back of the envelope calculation suggests that the immigra-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!