12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

148Gordon H HansonThe expansion of more efficient, skill <strong>in</strong>tensive plants may <strong>in</strong>crease the relativedemand for skilled labor. Theoretical research has only recently begun to addressthe issue. Helpman et al. (2008) developed a model <strong>in</strong> which trade can leadto higher wage <strong>in</strong>equality and greater unemployment <strong>in</strong> all economies (whenmov<strong>in</strong>g from autarky to free trade). Their framework depends on firms be<strong>in</strong>g imperfectly<strong>in</strong>formed about worker ability, and there be<strong>in</strong>g costly match<strong>in</strong>g of workersto firms, which together generate residual wage <strong>in</strong>equality that <strong>in</strong>creases asmore productive firms <strong>in</strong>crease their market share follow<strong>in</strong>g trade reform. In Indonesia,Amiti and Davis (2008) found that after trade reform, average wagesfell <strong>in</strong> import-compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries and rose <strong>in</strong> export<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries, which theysuggest is consistent with firm heterogeneity. Their results, however, depend onfirms sett<strong>in</strong>g wages accord<strong>in</strong>g to a ‘fairness’ pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, which is untested. The bottoml<strong>in</strong>e is that we have strong reason to expect that firm heterogeneity will mediatethe impact of trade shocks on wages, but we do not yet know whichmechanisms for transmission of the shocks are most relevant empirically.There has been considerably more research on how the global fragmentationof production affects the wage structure (see the survey <strong>in</strong> Feenstra and Hanson,2003). Mexico’s 1980s trade reform also liberalized foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment, whichwas followed by an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the relative wage of skilled labor (Hanson andHarrison, 1999). FDI <strong>in</strong> Mexican manufactur<strong>in</strong>g was concentrated <strong>in</strong> maquiladoras,many of which were created by US firms mov<strong>in</strong>g unskilled labor-<strong>in</strong>tensiveproduction activities to Mexico. Feenstra and Hanson (1997) found that the shift<strong>in</strong> Mexican manufactur<strong>in</strong>g toward export assembly plants can account for nearlyhalf of the observed <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the country’s demand for skilled labor (nonproductionworkers). Hsieh and Woo (2005) documented a similar phenomenon <strong>in</strong>Hong Kong and Ch<strong>in</strong>a. As Hong Kong moved labor-<strong>in</strong>tensive production activitiesto Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>in</strong> the 1980s and 1990s, the country saw an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the relativedemand for skill. Across Hong Kong manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries, Hsieh and Woo(2005) found a positive correlation between the nonproduction wage share andimports from Ch<strong>in</strong>a, which accounted for over half of the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the relativedemand for skilled workers that occurred <strong>in</strong> Hong Kong over the period.In Mexico, the effects of FDI on the wage structure appear to differ from thoseof tariff changes. Chiquiar (2008) found that dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s, when the NorthAmerican Free <strong>Trade</strong> Agreement was implemented, regions of Mexico closer tothe United States enjoyed higher wage growth and a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the return toschool<strong>in</strong>g, mean<strong>in</strong>g wage <strong>in</strong>equality with<strong>in</strong> these regions fell. In theory, as shownby Feenstra and Hanson (1997), it is possible for FDI and tariff reductions to affectwage <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> an oppos<strong>in</strong>g manner. In related work, Hanson (2007)found that regions of Mexico with more <strong>in</strong>itial FDI, more <strong>in</strong>itial trade with theUnited States, and greater emigration opportunities to the United States enjoyedhigher wage growth dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s.In the develop<strong>in</strong>g countries exam<strong>in</strong>ed by Goldberg and Pavcnik (2007)–Argent<strong>in</strong>a,Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, and Mexico—all experiencedan <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> wage <strong>in</strong>equality dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980s and 1990s. Which of these experiencescan be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by trade? While offshor<strong>in</strong>g appears important <strong>in</strong> Hong

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!