12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Adjustment</strong> to <strong>Trade</strong> Policy <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Countries</strong> 147that the skill-<strong>in</strong>tensive tasks performed <strong>in</strong> the North <strong>in</strong>clude fixed cost activities,such as management, research and development, and market<strong>in</strong>g, while the tasksperformed <strong>in</strong> the South <strong>in</strong>volve only variable cost production activities, offshor<strong>in</strong>gwill alter the relative volatility of output <strong>in</strong> the two countries. Berg<strong>in</strong> etal. (2009a) showed theoretically that a shock to, say, demand <strong>in</strong> the North willlead to greater changes <strong>in</strong> employment <strong>in</strong> the South, mean<strong>in</strong>g that offshor<strong>in</strong>g isassociated with the South hav<strong>in</strong>g higher volatility. Suppose the North has a positivedemand shock, which causes local production and wages to expand. Withhigher wages <strong>in</strong> the North, firms there that previously did not offshore any productionto the South now f<strong>in</strong>d it profitable to do so. <strong>Adjustment</strong> <strong>in</strong> the extensivemarg<strong>in</strong> of offshor<strong>in</strong>g transmits the shock to the South <strong>in</strong> a powerful manner,such that employment volatility is higher <strong>in</strong> the South than <strong>in</strong> the North. Berg<strong>in</strong>et al. (2009b) documented that employment volatility for maquiladoras <strong>in</strong> Mexicois greater than for the correspond<strong>in</strong>g manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>in</strong> the UnitedStates, even after controll<strong>in</strong>g for overall differences <strong>in</strong> the volatility of <strong>in</strong>dustrialproduction between the two countries. Through offshor<strong>in</strong>g, shocks to US manufactur<strong>in</strong>ghave a disproportionately large effect on Mexico.3. TRADE AND WAGESIn develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, fall<strong>in</strong>g trade barriers are associated with the exit of lessproductive firms, ris<strong>in</strong>g average <strong>in</strong>dustry productivity, greater fragmentation ofproduction, greater volatility of employment, and possibly more <strong>in</strong>formality.What do these changes mean for wages of develop<strong>in</strong>g country workers? Onedownside of the failure of the simple HO model is that few alternative models givemuch <strong>in</strong> the way of general results about how trade shocks affect wages. Theoretically,a wide range of outcomes are possible; empirically, a wide range of outcomeshave been observed. Rather than attempt<strong>in</strong>g to catalogue all of theseoutcomes, I focus on those that are most relevant to our discussion.It is perhaps useful to beg<strong>in</strong> with what we don’t know. One may expect thatchanges <strong>in</strong> the composition of firms due to trade liberalization would affect thelevel and structure of wages. However, there has been little connection betweenthe theoretical literature on firm heterogeneity and the empirical literature ontrade and wages. What might we expect to happen? As less productive and skill<strong>in</strong>tensive firms exit production and more productive and skill <strong>in</strong>tensive firms expand,workers who lose their jobs may see a drop <strong>in</strong> their earn<strong>in</strong>g power associatedwith the destruction of firm-specific human capital. In data for Mexico <strong>in</strong>the 1980s, Revenga (1997) found that wages for manufactur<strong>in</strong>g workers are positivelycorrelated with <strong>in</strong>dustry tariffs. As <strong>in</strong>dustry tariffs fall, <strong>in</strong>dustry wage premiado as well. Attanasio et al. (2004a) found similar evidence for Colombia;however, <strong>in</strong> a separate paper on Brazil (Attanasio et al. 2004b) they found no evidenceof changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry wage premia after trade reform. In the <strong>in</strong>stanceswhere it does occur, decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry average wages could reflect dislocationeffects by workers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry or the loss of rents, both of which could resultfrom a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> trade protection.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!