12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Transportation <strong>Costs</strong> and <strong>Adjustment</strong>s to <strong>Trade</strong> 259<strong>in</strong>g trade volumes promote entry <strong>in</strong>to shipp<strong>in</strong>g markets and pro-competitive effectson shipp<strong>in</strong>g markups, which can substantially lower shipp<strong>in</strong>g prices.On this last po<strong>in</strong>t, Hummels, Lugovskyy and Skiba (2009) systematically exam<strong>in</strong>ethe effect of market power <strong>in</strong> shipp<strong>in</strong>g. They report that <strong>in</strong> 2006 one <strong>in</strong> siximporter–exporter pairs was served by a s<strong>in</strong>gle l<strong>in</strong>er service, and over half wereserved by three or fewer. In general, large countries with higher trade volumesenjoy a greater number of shipp<strong>in</strong>g firms compet<strong>in</strong>g for their trade. To expla<strong>in</strong>these facts, Hummels, Lugovskyy and Skiba (2009) model the shipp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustryas a Cournot oligopoly and determ<strong>in</strong>e optimal shipp<strong>in</strong>g markups as a function ofthe number of carriers and the elasticity of transportation demand faced by carriers.A key <strong>in</strong>sight of the model is that transportation is not consumed directly;<strong>in</strong>stead, carriers face transportation demand derived <strong>in</strong>directly from import demand.This implies that the impact of an <strong>in</strong>creased shipp<strong>in</strong>g markup on the demandfor transportation depends on the share of transportation costs <strong>in</strong> thedelivered price of the good, and elasticity of import demand. The first effect isclosely related to the w<strong>in</strong>e bottle example above. For expensive goods, the marg<strong>in</strong>alcost of shipp<strong>in</strong>g represents a smaller fraction of the delivered product price,which enables cargo carriers to charge larger markups without a large demandresponse.The second effect relates to the responsiveness of trade volumes to <strong>in</strong>creasedprices. Suppose we have two goods for which shipp<strong>in</strong>g prices, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g markups,will yield an equal 5 per cent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the delivered price of the good. The firstgood is a differentiated product with import demand elasticity equal to 1.1. Here,a markup that yields a 5 per cent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> delivered price reduces traded quantities,and therefore demand for transportation services, by only 5.5 per cent. Thesecond good is a highly substitutable commodity and faces an import demandelasticity of 10. Here, the markup raises prices by 5 per cent but lowers quantitiestraded and demand for transportation services by 50 per cent! In the lattercase the identical markup reduces import (and therefore transportation) demandto a much greater degree, limit<strong>in</strong>g the carrier’s optimal markup.The implication is that the market power of shipp<strong>in</strong>g firms is extremely highwhen they are mov<strong>in</strong>g goods with <strong>in</strong>elastic import demand, and when marg<strong>in</strong>alcosts of shipp<strong>in</strong>g comprise a small fraction of the overall delivered price. In thesecases, it is easy to generate examples where optimal markups could be an order ofmagnitude higher than the marg<strong>in</strong>al cost of shipp<strong>in</strong>g. However, entry by rival l<strong>in</strong>ercompanies can very quickly erode this pric<strong>in</strong>g power. This suggests an especiallyimportant role for government policy <strong>in</strong> promot<strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong> the transportation<strong>in</strong>dustries. Not only is transport an <strong>in</strong>put <strong>in</strong>to merchandise trade, but trade <strong>in</strong>transportation services could yield substantial ga<strong>in</strong>s for the countries <strong>in</strong>volved.Such policy might take two forms. The first is regulat<strong>in</strong>g monopoly <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dustrythat may be ripe for collusive behavior. As an example, the European Union CompetitivenessCouncil recently concluded that cartelization <strong>in</strong> maritime shipp<strong>in</strong>g hadled to a less competitive shipp<strong>in</strong>g market and higher shipp<strong>in</strong>g prices. The Councilrepealed a long-stand<strong>in</strong>g block exemption to its competition laws that had allowedcarriers serv<strong>in</strong>g the European Union to collude <strong>in</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>g prices and market shares.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!