12.07.2015 Views

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: - World Bank ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

46Erhan Artuç and John McLaren<strong>in</strong> Artuç et al. (2010). However, <strong>in</strong> that study, the data set was 26 years long; <strong>in</strong>the present case, with only three years, that strategy is not available to us. We arehop<strong>in</strong>g that after the Turkish Statistical Institute releases two more years ofhousehold survey data, we will be able to use <strong>in</strong>struments, which is left over herefor future research. As an imperfect fix, we note that <strong>in</strong> the earlier paper with USdata, estimat<strong>in</strong>g with OLS <strong>in</strong>stead of with <strong>in</strong>struments <strong>in</strong>creased the value of Cby 67 per cent and v by 54 per cent when β = 0.97, and C by 34 per cent and vby 31 per cent when β = 0.9, so we divide our parameter estimates by 1.67, 1.54,1.34 and 1.31 for an alternative set of simulations. After simulat<strong>in</strong>g the modelwith orig<strong>in</strong>al estimates (for both β = 0.9 and β = 0.97), we repeat the simulationexercises with the corrected parameters, and show that the bias <strong>in</strong> the OLSestimates probably does not affect the adjustment path of workers and valuessignificantly.Table 3.4: Regression Results for Sector-specific Entry <strong>Costs</strong>Beta=0.97Beta=0.90Estimate t-statistic Estimate t-statisticv 1.60 (2.98***) 1.17 (3.95***)C 1 (Agriculture) 0.00 (0.00) 3.10 (1.53*)C 2 (Manufacture) 17.67 (2.41**) 7.17 (3.54***)C 3 (<strong>Trade</strong>) 9.90 (1.31) 5.55 (2.61***)C 4 (Service) 20.81 (5.52***) 8.65 (6.03***)T-statistics are <strong>in</strong> parentheses. One-tailed significance: 1-percent***, 5-percent**, 10-percent*.Another possible source of bias comes from the fact that we have imposeduniform mov<strong>in</strong>g costs for all sectors, so that. Degrees-of-freedomconcerns prevent us from estimat<strong>in</strong>g the full set of C ij parameters withoutrestriction, but we have also estimated the model with a slightly richerspecification allow<strong>in</strong>g for sector-specific entry costs. In this approach, C ij =C j fori=1,...,4. Table 3.4 shows the results of this regression.Compared with the Basic Model regression from Table 3.3, we f<strong>in</strong>d that all sectorsexhibit lower entry costs. However, we were not able to identify entry cost ofAgriculture when β = 0.97, therefore we are not us<strong>in</strong>g results from Table 3.4 <strong>in</strong>simulations. This identification problem probably arises because of our very smallsample size. We f<strong>in</strong>d that entry to the Service sector (which <strong>in</strong>cludes governmentand professional sectors) is the most costly one, while entry to Agriculture (which<strong>in</strong>cludes only workers who do not own a farm) is the least costly.4. SIMULATION: A SUDDEN TRADE LIBERALIZATIONNow, we use the estimates to study the effect of a hypothetical trade shockthrough simulations. Note that for the estimations, the only functional formassumption we needed was the density for the idiosyncratic shocks, but tosimulate the model we need to choose functional forms (and parameter values)for production and utility functions as well. We assume that each of the four

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!