09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECONOMIC VALUATION OF CULTURAL HERITAGE ■ 83<br />

in economics. Th e methodology to take account of various—priced and unpriced,<br />

direct, and indirect—eff ects is clearly not straightforward. One may broadly<br />

distinguish three major assessment classes for cultural assets: (1) performance<br />

indicators analysis, (2) monetary analysis, and (3) decision support analysis.<br />

Performance indicators analysis is a method that stems from the management<br />

literature and takes for granted that cultural heritage may be viewed, in the same<br />

way that a corporate organization is as an entity that may have to be judged on the<br />

basis of a set of predefi ned performance indicators. Th ese indicators may refer to<br />

heritage quality indices, conservation or rehabilitation risks, natural landscape<br />

conditions (using aerial photography, for instance), architectural identity, accessibility,<br />

integration into the urban fabric, uniqueness of historic districts, and so<br />

on. Methods used in this context, to obtain a systemic comparative framework<br />

are benchmark techniques and balance-scorecard techniques.<br />

Monetary analysis method has its origin in the applied welfare theory; it is<br />

based on the assumption that public policy serves to improve national welfare.<br />

To achieve this measure, public expenditures are to be made, but these expenditures<br />

are not aimed for general purposes but for specifi c goods and services in<br />

the framework of designated plans or projects. Th us, all cost components have to<br />

be measured as accurately as possible. Furthermore, the aim of national welfare is<br />

very broad and needs to be more focused, as usually not all individuals, groups,<br />

or regions in society will benefi t to the same extent from a plan or project. Hence,<br />

plans or projects have to be evaluated with a view to their foreseeable impact on<br />

diff erent groups or regions in a society; consequently, measurements of costs, of<br />

benefi ts, and of distributive eff ects are necessary.<br />

Th e conventional economic evaluation of cultural heritage usually fi nds its<br />

origin in the notion of consumer surplus, by way of incorporating the so-called<br />

travel cost method. Th is consumer surplus represents the consumer’s fi nancial<br />

sacrifi ces—represented in terms of distance a visitor is willing to travel and time<br />

he is willing to devote, the so-called willingness to pay minus the actual costs of<br />

a visit. Usual research methods used to assess this willingness to pay are, among<br />

others, based on survey techniques and interviews. A major problem in this case is<br />

the specifi cation of a demand function, because of heterogeneity among individual<br />

users, the importance of remaining (omitted) explanatory variables, synergetic<br />

eff ects caused by other recreation users (congestion, for example), the evaluation<br />

of time (or time preference), and the intangible nature of cultural heritage.<br />

Finally, the decision support analysis method is based on an operations<br />

research type of approach. Th is strand of literature rests on the proposition<br />

that cultural heritage has multiple use dimensions and that its societal signifi -<br />

cance is hard to translate in a single and unambiguous common denominator<br />

such as a monetary dimension. Examples in practical valuation exercises can be<br />

found in community impact analysis (Lichfi eld 1989) and multicriteria analysis

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!