09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

26 ■ THE <strong>ECONOMICS</strong> OF <strong>UNIQUENESS</strong><br />

and heritage values of the neighborhood, ΔV and ΔH, as given. In doing so, they<br />

neglect the impact of their own investment and demolition decisions on other<br />

properties around theirs. Th is coordination failure implies that, in general, the<br />

combination of all private investment decisions will not maximize the sum of<br />

private profi ts.<br />

Under relatively general assumptions, it can be shown that decentralized decisions<br />

result in both an insuffi cient volume of investment and an excessive amount<br />

of demolition. Th e word “insuffi cient” has a precise interpretation here. It means<br />

that if a single investor had to decide about the aggregate level of private spending<br />

I in the intervention area, he or she would go for a larger fi gure than the sum of<br />

all spending I i by local residents and outside developers. Similarly, if the intervention<br />

area includes n properties with architectural value, a single investor who<br />

owned the entire area would possibly choose to renovate and preserve k of them<br />

(with k ≤ n). But decentralized decisions by local residents and outside developers<br />

would result in fewer (and possibly none) of the properties surviving.<br />

First Externality: Insuffi cient Investment<br />

Ignore for a moment the fact that some properties in the intervention area have<br />

architectural value, and assume that all of them are generic buildings. Th e value<br />

of each of those properties increases by f' I units for each unit of investment in the<br />

property itself, and by f' V units when the average value of properties in the area<br />

goes up by one unit (the notation f' X is used to indicate the partial derivate of<br />

the hedonic price function f(.) with respect to argument X). Because decentralized<br />

investors take the average value of properties in the area as given, they only<br />

expect the value of their property to increase by f' I units if they invest one unit.<br />

But a single investor spending a unit on all properties in the area would internalize<br />

the fact that property prices are bound to increase by (1 + f' V ) × f' I . Because<br />

the expected monetary gain is bigger in the single investor’s case, he or she can be<br />

expected to spend more on each property.<br />

Th is point is made diagrammatically in fi gure 2.2. Th e assumptions made on<br />

the fi rst and second derivatives of the hedonic price function f(.) imply that ΔV i<br />

can be represented as a concave function of private investment spending I i . Each<br />

individual investor, taking the decisions of others as given, spends so as to maximize<br />

the net gain ΔV i − I i . In fi gure 2.2, this net gain is represented by the verti-<br />

cal distance between the function ΔV i and the 45 o line. Th e optimal spending,<br />

1 from a decentralized point of view, is therefore I . Th is spending yields a profi t<br />

i<br />

P i<br />

1 , represented by the solid bold line. It is assumed that project spending U on<br />

infrastructure makes this profi t strictly positive.<br />

However, with all individual investors making a similar decision, property<br />

prices increase not just by ΔV i but by (1 + f’ V ) × ΔV i . Once all private decisions are

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!