09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECONOMIC VALUATION OF CULTURAL HERITAGE ■ 95<br />

buys essentially a non-separable bundle of goods. A related problem is that the<br />

visitor to a cultural heritage good can derive utility from the trip itself or from<br />

the company in which the journey occurs (social externalities). Secondly, the<br />

opportunity costs of a visitor are hard to estimate; currently, the visitor’s wage<br />

is oft en used to value the opportunity cost (Navrud and Ready 2002). Th irdly,<br />

with travel cost methods, substitutes of cultural heritage can cause distortions<br />

and create diffi culties to assess direct eff ects. Finally, when people who choose to<br />

live in the vicinity of cultural heritage have a high preference for cultural assets,<br />

the distance to the cultural heritage site itself is then a residential location factor,<br />

which may cause complications in estimating the related demand function as the<br />

basis for economic valuation.<br />

Th e literature off ers various examples of cultural heritage studies that aim<br />

to estimate the values of these assets by means of the travel cost method. Th ese<br />

include the use of a site choice model to estimate the value of diff erent Dutch<br />

museums (Boter et al. 2005) and the estimate of the consumer surplus of four<br />

cultural heritage goods in the Castilla y Leon region in Spain on the basis of a<br />

travel cost method (Bedate et al. 2004). Another study used methods that combine<br />

the travel cost with contingent valuation carried out to value cultural heritage<br />

in Armenia; this approach also off ers interesting opportunities to separate<br />

use and non-use values (Alberini and Longo 2006). Th e approach of using travel<br />

cost studies has gained momentum in applied evaluation studies, despite the<br />

above-mentioned limitations.<br />

Hedonic Price Method<br />

Th e hedonic price method takes for granted that “goods are valued for their<br />

utility-bearing attributes or characteristics” (Rosen 1974). Th is approach is<br />

based on the idea that prices of heterogeneous goods stem from the characteristics<br />

of attribute variety. Although Rosen’s original analyses were developed<br />

for a market with perfect competition, the method is applicable under alternative<br />

market conditions (Bajari and Benkard 2005; Rouwendal and van der<br />

Straaten 2008). Clearly, hedonic price methods carry some intrinsic weaknesses.<br />

For example, a study points out that the measurement of diff erent attributes of<br />

the hedonic price method raises questions about the correct model specifi cation<br />

(Jones and Dunse 1996).<br />

In a later study, the same authors criticize the fact that the method reaches<br />

an equilibrium state throughout the property market and no interrelationship<br />

between the price of attributes is found (Dunse and Jones 1998). It is noteworthy<br />

that hedonic price analysis, in principle, may contain many variables that<br />

infl uence the value of real estate. In a conventional cross-section analysis, limited<br />

information on potentially relevant characteristics implies the risk of omitted<br />

variable bias. In addition, some other value determinants may be strongly

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!