09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

52 ■ THE <strong>ECONOMICS</strong> OF <strong>UNIQUENESS</strong><br />

assets and to the services they provide is an all-pervading problem, whether the<br />

value sought is economic, cultural, or a mix of the two.<br />

Th e distinction put forward earlier between the economic and the cultural<br />

value of heritage can now be elaborated in more detail.<br />

Economic Value<br />

As is the case with valuation of natural environments, it is customary in identifying<br />

the economic value of heritage assets to distinguish between use and non-use<br />

values, that is, between the direct value to consumers of the heritage services as a<br />

private good and the value accruing to those who experience the benefi ts of the<br />

heritage as a public good. Sometimes these eff ects are referred to, respectively, as<br />

market and non-market value.<br />

Th e use value of a heritage building is observed in several ways. Th e building<br />

may provide offi ce, retail, or other space to occupants who use the building for<br />

commercial purposes, in which case the actual or imputed rents paid serve as<br />

an indicator of the building’s value in use. Likewise the heritage asset may be a<br />

domestic dwelling where again rental rates or their equivalent are a measure of<br />

the private-good value of the services provided. In the case of heritage buildings<br />

and sites that are visited by tourists, use values are refl ected in the individual benefi<br />

ts that tourists enjoy as a result of their visit.<br />

A monetary indicator is provided by the entry price paid, enabling aggregation<br />

of a total use value generated by the building or site over a given period of<br />

time. Although such a calculation yields an estimate of fi nancial return, a complete<br />

account of the economic use benefi ts to tourists would need to include their<br />

consumer’s surplus as well. In addition, for many heritage sites visited by tourists,<br />

the use benefi ts would also include revenue from the commercial exploitation<br />

of the site via visitor centers where cafes, restaurants, and gift shops are located.<br />

Occasionally, a distinction is drawn between active use of a heritage building<br />

or site, such as those uses discussed above, and passive use that arises as an incidental<br />

experience for individuals, such as when pedestrians enjoy the aesthetic<br />

qualities of a historic building or site as they happen to pass by. Th is type of benefi<br />

t is classed as a positive externality. Although in principle a monetary value<br />

could be assigned to it, in practice it is usually ignored in any calculation of the<br />

economic value of cultural heritage because of diffi culties in defi ning appropriate<br />

populations of benefi ciaries and in identifying the willingness to pay (to protect<br />

or enjoy the asset) in valid terms.<br />

Turning to non-use value, we can observe that cultural heritage yields publicgood<br />

benefi ts that can be classifi ed in the same ways in which the non-market<br />

benefi ts of environmental amenities such as forests, wilderness areas, marine<br />

parks, and so on are determined. Th ree types of non-rival and non-excludable

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!