09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

222 ■ THE <strong>ECONOMICS</strong> OF <strong>UNIQUENESS</strong><br />

Understanding the context, objectives, and constraints of the diff erent private<br />

actors is, as Serageldin observes, like a Rubik’s cube that “requires patience, dedication<br />

and imagination” to fi gure out (Serageldin 1999). Although it is diffi cult,<br />

it is certainly feasible to pursue and mobilize private-sector investment and form<br />

partnerships with the public sector for the development of urban brownfi eld<br />

sites. Th e next sections of this chapter highlight the role of the public sector as<br />

prime mover and catalyst in leveraging resources and programs, and then examine<br />

four types of fi nancial partnership between the public and private sectors for<br />

urban brownfi eld investments.<br />

The Catalyst Player: The Role of Government<br />

Addressing urban brownfi elds presents particular challenges to national and<br />

regional policy-makers due to these sites’ signifi cant heritage legacies (cultural<br />

or natural) and potential for further development. Th ese areas are oft en<br />

left abandoned due to contamination, decay from lack of maintenance, limited<br />

access to transport, and depressed local economies. As numerous examples indicate<br />

(for instance, in Latin America; Marker et al. 2007), the high cost of facilitating<br />

the reintegration of rehabilitated sites—including natural areas and historic<br />

districts—into the property market and the lack of expertise in this fi eld oft en<br />

slow the process of transforming brownfi elds into new uses (Jackson and Garb<br />

2002). In general, public-sector fi nancial assistance is needed to make a sitereuse<br />

project economically viable, because remediation and preparation costs<br />

render many projects economically uncompetitive, at least initially (Kurdila and<br />

Rindfl eisch 2007; Meyer and Lyons 2000; Wernstedt et al. 2006). Th is can be<br />

overcome, however, by providing a range of coordinated inputs (e.g., policies,<br />

instruments, planning, funding, and training) to increase site attractiveness to<br />

the point where the market will take hold of the sites and exploit their potential,<br />

especially given their central locations. (See box 8.3.)<br />

Th e management of an increasing stock of derelict land and structures in<br />

inner-city locations is a pressing concern for urban planners and propertyrelated<br />

private stakeholders. When one considers the ongoing consumption of<br />

open space for housing, retail, and industry, it is clear that the goal of maintaining<br />

a sustainable built environment cannot be met without reintegrating brownfi elds<br />

into the property market and encouraging development back into central urban<br />

locations (RESCUE 2004). When new developments are built on city peripheries,<br />

the historic and post-industrial quarters in city centers almost always remain<br />

abandoned or partially occupied; for instance, this process is especially evident in<br />

the Central and Eastern Europe and the Baltic countries, as in the case of Tallin,<br />

the capital of Estonia (Cocconcelli and Medda 2010).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!