09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

116 ■ THE <strong>ECONOMICS</strong> OF <strong>UNIQUENESS</strong><br />

regulation means less value”—an argument frequently used by those who oppose<br />

heritage designation. In fact, the opposite has been proven to be true. Why? Later,<br />

this chapter will identify a number of likely contributing variables to this value<br />

premium, but the most basic reason comes from the real estate cliché: “Th e three<br />

most important things in real estate are location, location, location.” But cliché<br />

though it may be, there is an underlying reality that makes this premise valid.<br />

Note that the cliché is not: “Th e three most important things are roof, walls, and<br />

fl oor.” Th e majority of the economic value of a particular parcel of real estate<br />

comes not from within the property lines but from its context; that is, its location<br />

within a given neighborhood and its adjacent public facilities and natural<br />

and cultural surroundings. Th at is why identical houses in Mexico City, Hanoi,<br />

Prague, and Rabat will have dramatically diff erent values. But the comparison<br />

doesn’t have to cross international borders. As anyone who has bought, sold, or<br />

fi nanced real estate knows, even within a small city, the same house in a diff erent<br />

neighborhood will command a diff erent, sometimes dramatically diff erent,<br />

market value.<br />

Th e economic role of land-use laws in general, and historic designation<br />

in particular, is to protect the context within which the individual property<br />

is situated. No one pays a premium for a heritage house for the privilege of<br />

having to ask permission from some governmental body to put new shingles<br />

on the roof. Rather a homeowner will pay a premium for the assurance that<br />

the neighbor across the street will not be allowed to make inappropriate<br />

changes to his house that will have an adverse visual and value eff ect on the<br />

one’s own house.<br />

A sampling of studies demonstrates how this pattern manifests itself in<br />

the market place. A recent longitudinal study conducted in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania,<br />

United States, looked at property value changes over an extended<br />

period, 1980–2008 (Econsult Corporation 2010). Over this nearly 30-year timeframe,<br />

properties in both local historic districts and National Register historic<br />

districts saw rates of appreciation that outpaced the Philadelphia market in general,<br />

as shown in fi gure 5.1. Further, the study found that “homes in local historic<br />

districts enjoy an immediate 2 percent increase in values relative to the city average,<br />

once local designation has taken place; and thereaft er, they appreciate at an<br />

annual rate that is 1 percent higher than the city average.”<br />

In Philadelphia, the value premium attached to the local historic districts is<br />

8 percent greater than for the National Register districts. In Louisville, Kentucky,<br />

United States, researchers at the University of Louisville found that, over the<br />

period 2000 to 2007, properties in local historic districts commanded a premium<br />

of between US$59,000 and US$67,000 and that properties in those districts<br />

saw rates of appreciation 21 percent greater than in the Louisville market<br />

as a whole (Gilderbloom et al. 2009).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!