09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

62 ■ THE <strong>ECONOMICS</strong> OF <strong>UNIQUENESS</strong><br />

for example, in the area of design or safety standards governing public access<br />

to buildings and sites. In these situations, it may be desirable to leave nothing<br />

to chance, but rather ensure compliance for certain tough regulatory means.<br />

• Another advantage of regulations is that they may be invoked and removed<br />

relatively speedily. Th us, direct controls may be a useful supplement to other<br />

measures, such as a system of charges, for the continuing maintenance of<br />

acceptable environmental conservation or preservation conditions. Th eir usefulness<br />

arises because of the infl exibility of tax rates and other instruments,<br />

and the relative ease with which certain types of regulatory controls can be<br />

introduced, enforced, and removed. Some crises can at best be predicted only<br />

a short time before they occur, and it may be too costly, for example, to keep<br />

tax rates suffi ciently high to prevent such emergencies at all times. Th erefore,<br />

it may be less expensive to make temporary use of direct controls, despite their<br />

static ineffi ciency. Th is point is acknowledged in the fi eld of urban conservation<br />

through the use of temporary preservation orders; that is, controls that can<br />

be introduced at very short notice to forestall the demolition of historic properties<br />

until some due process of consultation or consideration can be pursued.<br />

Th e principal regulatory device that governments or other public authorities<br />

use in the heritage arena is “listing”; that is, the establishment of lists of properties<br />

within a given jurisdiction—international, national, regional, or local—that<br />

are regarded as being of cultural signifi cance. Criteria are generally laid down to<br />

specify the characteristics that defi ne cultural signifi cance such that any property<br />

meeting these criteria will be eligible for inclusion on a particular list.<br />

In most jurisdictions, the inclusion of privately owned buildings or groups<br />

of buildings on an offi cial, publicly sanctioned heritage list is compulsory, and<br />

the owners have no alternative but to comply with whatever requirements the<br />

list carries with it. In some cases, however, accession of properties to an offi cial<br />

heritage list is voluntary; in these cases the representativeness and comprehensiveness<br />

of the list is dependent on the willingness of private owners to comply<br />

with the set of obligations the listing process imposes on them. In addition to lists<br />

maintained and enforced by public-sector agencies, there are oft en “unoffi cial”<br />

lists maintained by interest groups, nongovernmental organizations, and so on,<br />

such as National Trusts and local history societies.<br />

Fiscal Incentives<br />

Governments can also employ fi scal measures to implement heritage policy,<br />

using both direct and indirect means to do so. Th e most visible direct approach<br />

is through government fi nancing of the conservation of heritage assets owned or<br />

controlled by public authorities at national or local levels, such as historic government<br />

buildings, public monuments, and so on. (See box 3.5.)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!