09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

22 ■ THE <strong>ECONOMICS</strong> OF <strong>UNIQUENESS</strong><br />

to a historic landmark or a distinct neighborhood. Th e other approach builds<br />

on urban economics, trying to assess how proximity to historic landmarks or to<br />

buildings with architectural value aff ects property prices. In this case, there is no<br />

attempt to attach a direct use value to aesthetics or culture, but rather to infer how<br />

they infl uence the price of assets for which a market does exist.<br />

An Environmental Economics Approach<br />

In the environmental economics approach, the value of protecting a historic landmark<br />

or a neighborhood with character is generally assessed by seeking views<br />

from the population at large (Pagiola 1996, Navrud and Ready 2002). When this<br />

is done by asking a direct question, the method is called “stated preferences.”<br />

When an indirect question is used instead, it is called “revealed preferences.” Th e<br />

latter method is more reliable if respondents have an incentive to understate their<br />

subjective valuation; for instance, if they fear that expressing their fondness for<br />

a landmark would make them shoulder a bigger share of the associated maintenance<br />

costs. An example of a direct question is: “How much would you be willing<br />

to pay to protect and maintain this historic building?” Th e potential free-rider<br />

problem calls for questions such as “How much would you be willing to spend in<br />

travel to visit this historical building?”<br />

While subjective valuations of this sort may yield some plausible fi gures for<br />

ΔH, they are not directly informative in relation to ΔV. Given the conceptual<br />

parallel between cultural and natural heritage, it is not surprising that those relying<br />

on the environmental economics approach oft en think of the monetary gains<br />

from the project in terms of increased tourism revenue in the intervention area.<br />

Let ΔY t be the additional tourism-related earnings local residents may derive for<br />

an urban upgrading project with a cultural dimension in year t, compared to their<br />

earnings in the absence of the project. In an effi cient property market, the value of<br />

land and dwellings in the area should increase by the present value of additional<br />

tourism revenue over the years. Assuming a zero discount rate for simplicity, the<br />

proponents of the environmental economics approach postulate:<br />

∑<br />

Δ V = ΔYt<br />

Th is is why several of the methods proposed in the literature focus on estimating<br />

ΔY t . Th e environmental economics approach is conceptually appealing, but<br />

it yields an underestimate of ΔV. Th e value of properties in the intervention area<br />

is likely to increase even in the absence of any additional tourism, because of the<br />

better urban infrastructure U provided by the project. Project-funded transfers<br />

T to local residents are also bound to result in improvements in the quality of<br />

t

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!