09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

xxii ■ OVERVIEW<br />

and captures the ways in which heritage investment contribute, in combination<br />

with other inputs, to the production of further cultural goods and services, job<br />

creation, and well being of local communities.<br />

Interpreting heritage as cultural capital has a clear parallel with the defi nition<br />

of environment as natural capital. Like any other form of capital, both cultural<br />

and natural capital have been inherited from the past, might deteriorate or<br />

depreciate if not maintained, and impose on the present generation a duty of care<br />

so they can be handed down to future generations. Th e long-term management of<br />

both cultural and natural capital has been integrated in sustainable development<br />

and experts have developed practical tools to operationalize this new paradigm.<br />

A central issue in heritage economics is the question of valuation of these<br />

assets. As is the case of environmental economics, it is customary to distinguish<br />

between use 3 and non-use values. 4 Th ese are also referred to, respectively, as<br />

market and non-market values. A third category of value—the cultural value 5 —<br />

should be added to the equation in order to capture the full benefi ts of heritage<br />

investment. While the fi rst two categories of value are easier to measure, cultural<br />

value, by contrast, is a multidimensional concept. Chapter 3 proposes that the<br />

various elements contributing to cultural value can be similarly assessed.<br />

Economic valuation of heritage investment evolved from methods traditionally<br />

used in environmental economics. Five valuation methods are used to<br />

address diff erent aspects of heritage valuation, and chapters 4 and 9 discuss their<br />

features. Th e fi rst method is compensation, which seeks to evaluate the cost and<br />

benefi ts derived from changes in the availability or quality of a heritage asset. Th e<br />

second method is social cost-benefi t analysis, which captures the benefi ts of an<br />

investment with large spill-over eff ects. Th e third method is stated preference,<br />

which is rooted in behavioral economics, and aims to uncover what individuals<br />

are willing to pay or accept when the availability of a public good changes. Th ere<br />

are also revealed preference methods, which include travel cost (fourth method)<br />

and hedonic price (fi ft h method). Travel cost is based on calculating the fi nancial<br />

sacrifi ce that a visitor makes to travel to a city or a site of cultural signifi cance, but<br />

it has some limits, especially due to attribution and opportunity cost.<br />

Th e hedonic price method, widely used in urban economics, is emerging<br />

as a better tool for evaluating heritage-related investments. Th is model can<br />

help gain a better understanding of the value of heritage assets by leveraging<br />

databases having detailed information on transactions in the real estate market.<br />

Such databases are especially useful if they comprise disaggregated data on<br />

the characteristics of the properties sold. In this context, Geographic Information<br />

System (GIS) techniques oft en off er the possibility to further enrich data<br />

with mapping of information about geographic neighborhood characteristics.<br />

It is, however, important that this method takes distributional implications into

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!