09.03.2013 Views

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

ECONOMICS UNIQUENESS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECONOMIC VALUATION OF CULTURAL HERITAGE ■ 87<br />

of accurate physical-biological indicators, should be assessed. Biodiversity<br />

changes must be marginal or small for economic valuation to make sense.<br />

Th e economic valuation of biodiversity changes is based on a reductionist<br />

approach to value. Th is means that the total economic value is regarded as<br />

the result of aggregating various use and non-use values, refl ecting a variety<br />

of human motivations, as well as aggregating local values to attain a global<br />

value, in a bottom-up approach (Nunes and Schokkaert 2003).<br />

Moreover, the economic valuation of biodiversity starts from the premise that<br />

social values should be based on individual values, independently of whether the<br />

individuals are knowledgeable about biodiversity-related issues or not. Th is can<br />

be considered consistent with the democratic support of policies.<br />

Biodiversity—like cultural heritage—describes a complex system. Hence, it<br />

is not plausible that an unambiguous value indicator can be derived. Nevertheless,<br />

several partial studies help to reveal aspects of this multidimensional whole<br />

(Nunes and Nijkamp 2011).<br />

Which lessons can we draw from a comparison with the biodiversity valuation?<br />

It is striking that the nature of the underlying issues are largely similar—<br />

such as long-term perspective, economic externalities, and psychological or<br />

spiritual attachment. In economic terms, it comes as no surprise that the array<br />

of evaluation methods used in both domains is quite similar. Th e costs of policy<br />

interventions in these domains are made up by direct capital outlays for<br />

the implementation, necessary wage costs, factor supply costs, overhead costs,<br />

opportunity costs, and social costs. Social costs may either be quantifi able or not,<br />

but refer to all costs incurred that are not refl ected in the usual market mechanism.<br />

In all cases it is desirable to measure costs in terms of current factor input<br />

prices, among others, due to information comparison.<br />

In the case of public projects, market prices for goods and services are usually<br />

not easily available, although for such cases proxy values for costs may be<br />

imagined and used, such as social marginal costs (for instance, a charge to the<br />

user of an output equal to the benefi t received), shadow prices (based on a linear<br />

programming approach), and marginal costs (based on standard economic equilibrium<br />

assumptions). It is plausible to derive some important lessons from biodiversity<br />

economics, but it is also clear that cultural heritage has its own indigenous<br />

features that call for tailor-made valuation methods. Th ese are discussed next.<br />

The Economist’s Toolbox<br />

Th e economic valuation of cultural heritage projects essentially fi nds its roots<br />

in the evaluation of non-priced goods, in particular arising from evaluation of<br />

environmental goods. Th e overarching aim is to attach a price tag to such goods.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!