04.01.2014 Views

Report

Report

Report

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

26 QUANTIFICATION OF BENEFITS FROM ECONOMIC COOPERATION IN SOUTH ASIA<br />

Baysan and Panagriya (2006) examine the economic<br />

case for SAFTA. They study SAFTA in the light of<br />

the preferential trading arrangements in the region,<br />

particularly ISFTA, in order to draw lessons. Subsequently<br />

they examine the qualitative and quantitative<br />

arguments to assess the feasibility of SAFTA. The results<br />

are mostly pessimistic. The following qualitative<br />

arguments fail to provide a strong case in favour of<br />

SAFTA. Firstly, the economies are relatively small as<br />

compared to the rest of the world both in terms of GDP<br />

and trade flows. The economic size of the region<br />

remains small: less than one-twentieth of the world in<br />

terms of GDP. If we exclude India, this figure drops to<br />

0.4%. Consequently, the probability that the most<br />

efficient suppliers of the member countries are within<br />

the region is slim. Hence an FTA is likely to be largely<br />

trade diverting.<br />

Secondly, the level of protection amongst SAARC<br />

countries is very high with the exception of Sri Lanka.<br />

If a country participating in a regional arrangement<br />

were not open they are likely to suffer from welfare<br />

losses due to trade diversion. The third reason which<br />

makes the economic case for SAFTA weak is political<br />

economy of selection of the excluded sectors and rules<br />

of origin (ROO) issue. This leads to inefficient selection<br />

as domestic lobbies make sure that the sectors that do<br />

not withstand competition are excluded from tariff<br />

preferences and lobbies go along free trade in sectors<br />

in which they are competitive. A similar pattern is<br />

observed in case of ROO. A common argument advanced<br />

in favour of SAFTA is that there is substantial informal<br />

trade between countries. There are three arguments<br />

relating to this issue. First, if the real costs associated<br />

with informal trade are higher, benefits of such cost<br />

saving need to be weighed against cost of trade diversion.<br />

Second, an FTA might make formal trade even<br />

more expensive than informal trade by adding to the<br />

costs of complying with the ROO. Third, all the<br />

informal trade between India and Pakistan may not be<br />

due to restrictions that preclude trade at the MFN terms<br />

and a part of it may try to evade even the MFN tariff.<br />

Apart from the theoretical arguments, quantitative<br />

studies that have estimated the impact of SAFTA have<br />

used mainly three types of models, that are either gravity<br />

models; or general equilibrium models; or partial<br />

equilibrium models. The studies employing gravity<br />

models predict that the impact of a South Asian FTA<br />

will be small for India and much larger on the smaller<br />

countries. Second, amongst studies using CGE models<br />

to SAFTA, there are two important studies, Pigato et<br />

al. (1997) and Shakur and Rae (2005). Pigato et al.<br />

find that the unilateral trade liberalisation yields larger<br />

gains than SAFTA. Shakur and Rae find that SAFTA<br />

leads to a 0.21% gain in real income in India, 0.03%<br />

gain for Srilanka and a loss of 0.10% for Bangladesh.<br />

The largest gain of 0.21% is too low and the authors<br />

conclude that the South Asian countries will gain much<br />

more from unilateral/multilateral liberalisation.<br />

The third types of studies have employed partial<br />

equilibrium models. Govindan (1994) concludes that<br />

liberalisation would yield welfare gains through<br />

increased trade within the region. Derosa and Govindan<br />

(1996) further demonstrate that the gains are much<br />

larger when liberalisation is on a non-discriminatory<br />

basis. Given, the pessimistic economic assessment the<br />

study indicates that the move toward SAFTA gained<br />

momentum due to political reasons such as with the<br />

entire world moving ahead with more and more PTAs,<br />

there is an element of following a trend around the<br />

world. Also, SAFTA is seen as a vehicle for promoting<br />

political ties between India and Pakistan. The case of<br />

India and Pakistan is often compared to France and<br />

Germany but the differences in the two situations raise<br />

serious doubts about the validity of the argument.<br />

On the whole, it can be said that the pessimism<br />

with respect to gains from SAFTA arises mainly because<br />

of lack of economic conditions for success of RTA,<br />

which are trade complementarities and differences in<br />

competitiveness of the countries. Empirical literature<br />

suggests that the existence of complementarities is<br />

needed to enhance the probability of a regional trade<br />

arrangement to be net trade-creating, rather than net<br />

trade-diverting. The statistical measures such as the<br />

complementarity index argue that the higher the<br />

observed values of the index between partners, the more<br />

likely is it that a proposed regional trade agreement<br />

will succeed (Michaely 1996). Indices of trade complementarity<br />

developed by Drysdale (1969) have been used<br />

by Kemal et al. (2000) to estimate the complementarity<br />

indices for all five leading South Asian countries using<br />

time series trade data. It was found that there is a lack<br />

of strong trade complementarity in the bilateral trade<br />

structures of South Asia. Lack of trade complementarities<br />

raises the questions on the future prospects of SAFTA.<br />

To identify different countries’ competitiveness<br />

among different commodity groups, the export revealed<br />

comparative advantage (XRCA) indices have been<br />

estimated by some studies at the three-digit level<br />

(Samaratunga 1999 and Kemal et al. 2000), which<br />

show that the comparative advantage countries in South<br />

Asia have an almost identical pattern of comparative<br />

advantage in a relatively narrow band of commodities.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!