15.02.2014 Views

The Benefits to Taxpayers from Increases in Students - RAND ...

The Benefits to Taxpayers from Increases in Students - RAND ...

The Benefits to Taxpayers from Increases in Students - RAND ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Analytic Approach 23<br />

<strong>The</strong> differences between the two sets of results estimate the effects of <strong>in</strong>creased educational<br />

atta<strong>in</strong>ment on government revenues over an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s lifetime, hold<strong>in</strong>g his or<br />

her characteristics constant.<br />

We use a similar approach <strong>to</strong> estimate the effects of <strong>in</strong>creased educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment<br />

on the costs of subsidized hous<strong>in</strong>g. We use the model of hous<strong>in</strong>g subsidy utilization<br />

<strong>to</strong> estimate the probability that an <strong>in</strong>dividual with given demographic characteristics<br />

and education level would utilize assisted hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each year of his or her life<br />

<strong>from</strong> school-leav<strong>in</strong>g age <strong>to</strong> age 79. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that the unit hous<strong>in</strong>g cost per person is<br />

constant across education levels and demographic groups, the expected hous<strong>in</strong>g subsidy<br />

is equal <strong>to</strong> the likelihood of utilization, as predicted by the model, times the average<br />

program cost per person. We then discount the estimates for each year of an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s<br />

life <strong>to</strong> age 18, us<strong>in</strong>g appropriate survival rates. <strong>The</strong> result is an estimate of the<br />

present value at age 18 of the assisted hous<strong>in</strong>g benefits that would be paid <strong>to</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

<strong>from</strong> that demographic group between school-leav<strong>in</strong>g and age 79, given his or<br />

her education level. We then compare the results for an <strong>in</strong>dividual with a given level of<br />

education and characteristics aga<strong>in</strong>st the correspond<strong>in</strong>g results for an <strong>in</strong>dividual with<br />

the same characteristics but a higher level of education. <strong>The</strong> differences between the<br />

two sets of results estimate the effects of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dividual’s level of education<br />

on the assisted hous<strong>in</strong>g benefits paid an <strong>in</strong>dividual over his or her lifetime, hold<strong>in</strong>g his<br />

or her characteristics constant.<br />

For each of the other social support and <strong>in</strong>surance programs, we use the probit<br />

model for that program <strong>to</strong> estimate the likelihood that an <strong>in</strong>dividual with given characteristics<br />

and education level will participate <strong>in</strong> that program <strong>in</strong> each year of his or her<br />

life <strong>from</strong> school-leav<strong>in</strong>g age <strong>to</strong> age 79. We then use the model of the annual <strong>in</strong>come<br />

the <strong>in</strong>dividual will receive <strong>from</strong> that program if they participate <strong>in</strong> any given year. We<br />

multiply the likelihood that the <strong>in</strong>dividual will participate <strong>in</strong> the program <strong>in</strong> each year<br />

by the estimated benefits that the <strong>in</strong>dividual would receive <strong>in</strong> that year if he or she participated<br />

<strong>to</strong> estimate the expected value of the program benefits paid <strong>to</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

<strong>in</strong> each year. We discount the estimates for each year of an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s life <strong>to</strong> age 18,<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g appropriate survival rates. <strong>The</strong> result is an estimate of the present value at age 18<br />

of the benefits an <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>from</strong> that demographic group will receive between school<br />

leav<strong>in</strong>g and age 79, given his or her education level. We then compare the results for an<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual with a given level of education and characteristics aga<strong>in</strong>st the correspond<strong>in</strong>g<br />

results for an <strong>in</strong>dividual with the same characteristics but a higher level of education<br />

<strong>to</strong> estimate the effects of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment on the program’s costs over the <strong>in</strong>dividual’s<br />

lifetime, hold<strong>in</strong>g his or her characteristics constant.<br />

As noted previously, we model per-person correctional spend<strong>in</strong>g as the product<br />

of per-person <strong>in</strong>carceration expenditure and the likelihood of <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong>carceration,<br />

assum<strong>in</strong>g that the probability of <strong>in</strong>carceration equals the number of prisoners <strong>in</strong> each<br />

population category divided by the sum of the general population and the number

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!