15.02.2014 Views

The Benefits to Taxpayers from Increases in Students - RAND ...

The Benefits to Taxpayers from Increases in Students - RAND ...

The Benefits to Taxpayers from Increases in Students - RAND ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Spend<strong>in</strong>g on Social Support Programs 43<br />

As discussed <strong>in</strong> Chapter Two, greater educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment leads <strong>to</strong> better<br />

opportunities <strong>in</strong> the job market. Higher levels of education result <strong>in</strong> both higher likelihood<br />

of employment and higher earn<strong>in</strong>gs when employed. <strong>The</strong> decision <strong>to</strong> participate<br />

<strong>in</strong> a social support program is dictated by a comparison of the benefits available <strong>from</strong><br />

that program and the earn<strong>in</strong>gs forgone <strong>in</strong> the labor market. <strong>The</strong> more educated the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual, the more he or she can command <strong>in</strong> the labor market. <strong>The</strong>refore, <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

education makes social support program participation less attractive. Moreover, most<br />

social support programs have str<strong>in</strong>gent participation criteria related <strong>to</strong> current <strong>in</strong>come<br />

or assets. Anyth<strong>in</strong>g that improves a person’s earn<strong>in</strong>gs potential reduces his or her participation<br />

<strong>in</strong> social support programs. Further, the benefits provided <strong>to</strong> participants <strong>in</strong><br />

most social support programs are <strong>in</strong>versely related <strong>to</strong> the participant’s <strong>in</strong>come. Higher<br />

earn<strong>in</strong>g participants receive lower benefits <strong>in</strong> most social support programs.<br />

<strong>The</strong> converse is true for most social <strong>in</strong>surance programs. Eligibility for some social<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance programs depends on hav<strong>in</strong>g been employed for some period of time, and<br />

the amount of benefits provided <strong>to</strong> a beneficiary sometimes depend on the amounts<br />

paid <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> the program by the beneficiary or on behalf of the beneficiary. Because more<br />

highly educated <strong>in</strong>dividuals are more likely <strong>to</strong> be employed and likely <strong>to</strong> earn more<br />

when employed, more highly educated people are more likely <strong>to</strong> qualify for social<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance and likely <strong>to</strong> receive higher benefits when they draw on the program.<br />

Program utilization and benefits are a function of <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>dividual attributes,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g education level. But aga<strong>in</strong>, education level directly affects earn<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

and, consequently, directly affects both participation <strong>in</strong> welfare programs and the<br />

amount received when participat<strong>in</strong>g. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, we develop two types of reduced<br />

form models: those that estimate the relationship between program participation and<br />

education level and other personal characteristics, and those that estimate the relationship<br />

between program benefits and education and other personal characteristics<br />

We obta<strong>in</strong>ed program participation data <strong>from</strong> the 2002 SIPP for the eight programs<br />

we consider. <strong>The</strong> SIPP also provides data on the amount of benefit received by<br />

the <strong>in</strong>dividual or family for welfare, food stamps, Unemployment Insurance, SSI, and<br />

Social Security. In each of these programs, we use a two-part model <strong>to</strong> assess the effect<br />

of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment on program benefits. In the first stage, we model program<br />

utilization as a function of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment, age, gender, race/ethnicity, and<br />

place of birth. In the second stage, for those who are program participants, we model<br />

annual <strong>in</strong>come <strong>from</strong> the particular program as a function of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment,<br />

age, gender, race/ethnicity, and place of birth. F<strong>in</strong>ally, we comb<strong>in</strong>e results <strong>from</strong> both<br />

models <strong>to</strong> derive program benefits by education level.<br />

For Medicare and Medicaid, we use 2002 utilization data <strong>from</strong> the SIPP and 2002<br />

program benefit data <strong>from</strong> the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services of the U.S.<br />

Department of Health and Human Services. Because these data are not stratified by<br />

education or any other variable we’re <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>, we assume that that Medicare and<br />

Medicaid cost per user is constant across education levels and demographic groups. We<br />

use average payment per beneficiary or service user for <strong>in</strong>patient and outpatient ser-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!