31.05.2021 Views

CALGARY EDITION JUNE 2021

CALGARY EDITION JUNE 2021

CALGARY EDITION JUNE 2021

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

were not forced to sell at extremely low

rates. Vast market areas were created where

government-regulated agricultural

commerce could take place. Mandis, though

riddled with longstanding issues and in need

of serious reform, have been vital to

agricultural life. The new Farmers’ Produce

Trade and Commerce (Promotion and

Facilitation) Act takes a sledgehammer to

this system, promising privatisation of the

procurement regime and more remunerative

prices.

Much has been made about the entry of

private players into agricultural purchase,

but the truth is that several states had made

way for them well before the new central

law. What the central government is really

seeking to do is allow the unregulated entry

of private players into the agriculture sector.

As the case of Bihar has shown, this has

not exactly been a boon for farmers.

In 2017, Punjab had already passed an

amended Agriculture Produce Market

Committee Act that allowed private players

to purchase produce at existing mandis. The

contrast between Punjab’s amended act and

the law passed by the Modi government is

illustrative. Under the FPTC Act, all private

players can purchase crops anywhere they

want as long as they have a PAN card. There

are nearly no regulations constraining such

players, except that they make payments

within three working days, barring which

the matter must be resolved mutually or

taken up before the local sub-divisional

magistrate. Whether the buyers are fly-bynight

operators or big players, in the

absence of state regulation the farmer is

effectively left with no protection at all.

In contrast, the Punjab act only allows

those who are issued licences by the state.

They can procure at government mandis,

or at private mandis that have to follow

APMC norms, including the payment of

taxes which include a market fee for

maintaining the mandi, a commission for

brokers called arhtiyas, and a ruralinfrastructure

cess. Punjab imposes a total

tax of 8.5 percent, while Haryana imposes

6.5 percent.

The market fees maintain infrastructure

at the mandis, the rural cess is used to

maintain rural roads and infrastructure and

the arhtiyas’ commission is in return for

services such as cleaning, weighing and

sorting grain before it is procured. The

arhtiyas are vital to the functioning of the

mandis, and their reputation as predators

largely comes from their doubling up as

Buy/Sell/Lease, Any kind of Real Estate : 403-681-8689

moneylenders. Even this is a role for which

the central government is offering no better

substitute. Certainly, corporate buyers are

not inclined to issue cash advances in the

absence of collateral.

The new farm laws cut arhtiyas and the

rural cess out of the picture, and even

disallow any market-fee payment by the

Food Corporation of India. The FCI’s

godowns are now meant to count as private

mandis, where the cess and market fee do

not apply. This is where the strongest

apprehensions about the government’s

intentions surface. The existing mandi

infrastructure in Punjab, and to a lesser

extent in Haryana, functions well and

ensures that procurement is a smooth

process, with very few complaints by the

farmers. This is an infrastructure that is

sustained by the market fee. In the absence

of this fee from the FCI, and much of the

procurement moving out elsewhere, a large

amount of the revenue that sustains the state

mandi infrastructure will disappear.

There are a great number of practical

difficulties if the FCI is to acquire grain

directly at its godowns. These godowns are

nowhere near as numerous as the mandis,

which are present every eight to ten

kilometres. In any case, even if farmers

bring grain directly to the godowns,

increasing their transportation costs, the

need for unloading, cleaning and weighing

the grain will remain. Either the FCI passes

these costs on to the farmer or it bears them

itself, neither of which is an improvement

over the current arrangement.

The consequences of the kind of

breakdown of the APMC mandi system that

these new laws threaten are already seen in

Bihar, where the APMC Act was abolished

in 2006. In a piece in the Hindustan Times,

Sukhpal Singh of the Indian Institute of

Management, Ahmedabad, noted that while

the number of procurement centres in Bihar

declined drastically over the past five years”

from 9,035 in 2015-16 to 1,619 in 2019-20"

the number of these centres in Punjab,

Haryana, Uttar Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh

increased during the same period.

Clearly, the privatisation of procurement

will not necessarily improve infrastructure.

What, then, of the other great promise of

remunerative prices? The repeated claim

made on behalf of the government is that

the sums saved from the removal of the

mandi cess will be passed on to farmers.

Once again, Bihar provides a telling

example. “During 2016-17, the MSP for

wheat, paddy and maize was fixed as Rs

1,625, Rs 1,410 and Rs 1,365 but the

farmers could get Rs 1,299, Rs 1,113, and

Rs 1,140 a quintal, respectively,” Sukhpal

Singh writes. “During 2019-20, the farmers

got Rs 350-450 a quintal lower than the

MSP for all major crops.”

So, as far as the two major foodgrain

crops of the country wheat and rice are

concerned, the MSP combined with the

APMC procurement system was ensuring

prices of three hundred to four hundred

rupees more per quintal than in the

privatised procurement regime of Bihar.

The supposed saving was not being passed

on to customers in the state. Privatisation,

ostensibly meant to squeeze out middlemen,

only ended up fattening them in Bihar. What

the protesting farmers claim will happen

with the new laws has already come to pass

in Bihar procurement infrastructure has

collapsed, private traders have a monopoly

and purchase prices for farmers have

plummeted.

In the face of these facts, those who

advocate for the laws again invoke the

exceptional nature of those who benefit

under the old system.

Ashok Gulati, who is also on a Supreme

Court-appointed panel tasked with

preparing a report on the new laws, argues

that the old system has benefited only a

miniscule minority:

What is the reality about MSP? The

NSSO’s Situation Assessment Survey (70th

round) revealed that in 2012-13, only 6 per

cent of farmers sold their produce at MSP.

And of course, a majority of them were from

the Punjab-Haryana belt … And remember,

the MSP and APMC system primarily helps

those who have large surpluses, mainly the

large farmers … So, those who are arguing

for APMC mandis and MSP are basically

arguing for those 6 per cent of farmers or 6

per cent of the value of agri-produce.

Gulati’s use of these figures is a sleight

of hand, because they conceal far more than

they reveal. The NSSO data cited counts

all farmers in the country producing any

crop. To invoke the MSP regime in this

context makes no sense because there is no

purchase at MSP for the vast majority of

crops, and hence for the vast majority of

farmers. The absence of a system cannot

be used to argue against it. All this suggests

is that a great number of farmers already

experience the system the government is

now threatening to impose on everyone.

(Cont. on next issue)

Sikh Virsa, Calgary 94. June 2021

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!