15.11.2014 Views

Risk Management and Value Creation in ... - Arabictrader.com

Risk Management and Value Creation in ... - Arabictrader.com

Risk Management and Value Creation in ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Rationales for <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>in</strong> Banks 77<br />

vantages of their part of the firm’s cash flows because they are utility maximizers,<br />

113 <strong>and</strong> so on).<br />

If capital markets are less than perfect, the risk management irrelevance<br />

proposition does not hold anymore. Therefore, under these more realistic<br />

assumptions, the value of the firm can be <strong>in</strong>creased when risk tak<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong><br />

a firm is rewarded more highly than what can be achieved by sell<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the risk to the capital markets, that is, than what someone else would be<br />

will<strong>in</strong>g to pay for bear<strong>in</strong>g the same risk. 114 From this, one can directly deduce<br />

that, <strong>in</strong> this world, it is not the purpose of risk management to protect<br />

the firm’s value aga<strong>in</strong>st changes <strong>in</strong> market values at any price. These changes<br />

can occur, but shareholders are still able to adjust their exposure, just as <strong>in</strong><br />

the neoclassical world, to the various risk factors accord<strong>in</strong>g to their preferences.<br />

The purpose of risk management is rather to reduce the frictional<br />

costs that are associated with these changes <strong>in</strong> market values <strong>and</strong> to create<br />

value by do<strong>in</strong>g so.<br />

These frictional costs can stem from the follow<strong>in</strong>g market imperfections,<br />

115 which are a relaxation of the assumptions of the M&M world:<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

Asymmetric <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

Agency problems <strong>and</strong> management <strong>in</strong>centive structures<br />

Limited availability of external funds (i.e., external funds are costly)<br />

Transaction costs<br />

(Direct <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>direct) default costs<br />

(Convex schedule of) taxes<br />

Additionally, one should also assume that <strong>in</strong>vestment opportunities are<br />

stochastic, that is, the <strong>in</strong>vestment program is not fixed <strong>and</strong> dependent on the<br />

prevail<strong>in</strong>g economic conditions <strong>and</strong>, hence, a function of the cash flows<br />

generated by the firm’s assets <strong>in</strong> place. 116<br />

Irrespective of these relaxed assumptions, the basic work<strong>in</strong>gs of the<br />

neoclassical world are still valid, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestors are still able to adjust their<br />

portfolios <strong>and</strong> can undo corporate decisions by home-made risk management.<br />

It is therefore obvious, as long as <strong>in</strong>vestors are well-diversified, 117 that<br />

it is unlikely that risk-management decisions by the firm can <strong>in</strong>fluence the<br />

denom<strong>in</strong>ator of Equation (2.1) by chang<strong>in</strong>g the systematic risk. If risk<br />

management does not reduce the firm’s required rate of return, then it must<br />

113 See Jensen <strong>and</strong> Meckl<strong>in</strong>g (1976), p. 308.<br />

114 See Stulz (2000), p. 3-3.<br />

115 See Pritsch <strong>and</strong> Hommel (1997), p. 675.<br />

116 See Froot et al. (1993), p. 1638.<br />

117 See for example, Fenn et al. (1997), pp. 13+, <strong>and</strong> Smith (1993), pp. 17+.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!