25.03.2013 Views

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

— Michael Jursa —<br />

cereal farming always remained the principal agricultural activity; date gardening in<br />

the vicinity of urban centres, while still important and yielding high returns, was<br />

only of secondary importance overall. <strong>The</strong>se differences are one of several indications<br />

suggesting an economic dichotomy between northern Babylonia and the central and<br />

southern parts of the country. 4 Another important distinction is that between the<br />

agricultural landscape in close vicinity of the cities and that in more remote parts of<br />

the country. Land use around the cities was always much more intensive and geared<br />

towards supplying the urban centres and less towards subsistence agriculture for the<br />

benefit of the rural population. It can be shown, for instance, that the immediate<br />

hinterland of Babylon was characterised by very intensive market gardening.<br />

<strong>The</strong> single most important land owners were the institutions. <strong>The</strong> majority of the<br />

temples’ holdings – far better attested than royal land – were concentrated around<br />

their home cities, but in the case of the two best-known temples, the Ebabbar in<br />

northern Sippar and the Eanna in southern Uruk, it can be demonstrated that numerous<br />

estates were, in fact, situated at a considerable distance from the urban centre. <strong>The</strong><br />

Ebabbar, for instance, owned fields and gardens in the vicinity of Borsippa and Dilbat,<br />

south of Babylon. <strong>The</strong> cultivation of temple estates was achieved partly by the temples’<br />

own dependants, ploughmen and gardeners, who were, in all likelihood, unfree serfs<br />

(Akkadian sˇirku). However, their number was always insufficient for the agricultural<br />

needs of the temples. <strong>The</strong>refore, at all times, the land that had to be rented out to<br />

share croppers, free gardeners and other contractors exceeded the part of the temple<br />

domain that was under direct management. Not infrequently, large-scale leasing and<br />

sub-leasing took place. In this way, private entrepreneurs took part in the cultivation<br />

of institutional land. <strong>The</strong> so-called rent farmers were contractors undertaking the<br />

management of significant parts of the temple estates (or even of the entire holdings<br />

of a temple) against the payment of a predetermined rent. Initially, these men, who<br />

first appear late during the reign of Nebuchadrezzar II, in the first half of the sixth<br />

century, were royal protégées, later, during the rule of the Achaemenids, they could<br />

also originate in the temple households themselves. In theory, such entrepreneurs<br />

were supposed to be supplied with the necessary means for cultivating the land entrusted<br />

to them by the temples, but in practice they always had to invest at least<br />

part of their private means (which therefore had to be considerable) as well. <strong>The</strong><br />

temples (and thus, indirectly, the crown) expected from such contractors not only a<br />

simplification of the bureaucratic tasks of supervising cultivation and the payment<br />

of rents and dues, but also the availability of outside capital. <strong>The</strong> entrepreneurs, of<br />

course, hoped to make a profit beyond the fixed rent that was expected of them.<br />

As far as we can tell from the not over-abundant sources, royal estates and holdings<br />

of members of the king’s family and of high officials were managed along the same<br />

lines as lands of the temples, which could not really be considered as totally independent<br />

since their resources could always be drawn upon by the royal administration when<br />

necessary. In addition to direct management and farming out, royal land could be<br />

exploited in a third way, for instance by apportioning it to royal dependants who,<br />

in return, owed the state labour or military service and/or tax payments. Frequently,<br />

such estates were granted to various collectives, sometimes of a certain professional<br />

background, but more frequently of common, usually non-<strong>Babylonian</strong>, origin. <strong>The</strong><br />

land-for-service scheme was the easiest way by which the royal administration could<br />

integrate outsiders into <strong>Babylonian</strong> society. 5 Such settlements of non-<strong>Babylonian</strong>s<br />

226

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!