25.03.2013 Views

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

— <strong>The</strong> <strong>Babylonian</strong> economy in the first millennium BC —<br />

Agricultural management and the trade in agricultural staples was probably the<br />

most important occupation of <strong>Babylonian</strong> entrepreneurs. Gardeners or farmers renting<br />

land from city-based property owners on share-cropping or other terms cannot be<br />

considered to fall within this category. But there was a wide range of entrepreneurial<br />

activities going on just one level above that of the actual cultivators, and extending<br />

far up the social scale, up to the important rent farmers to whom the management<br />

of institutional land and canals was contracted out. Frequently, for instance, entrepreneurs<br />

would rent land and sublease it either to dependants or to free tenants,<br />

whom they would supply with the means necessary for their work. <strong>The</strong> profit would<br />

be shared, and only a comparatively small part of the rent would go to the land<br />

owner. Especially institutional land was often managed by a hierarchy of such businessmen<br />

who leased land from, and subleased land to, yet other entrepreneurs. Another<br />

area where private businessmen and institutions frequently interacted was animal<br />

husbandry: the temples’ and king’s flocks were often managed by entrepreneurs who<br />

took a share in the proceeds.<br />

An involvement in the trade in wool, staples, and beer brewed from dates was a<br />

natural consequence of entrepreneurial activities in the areas of agriculture and animal<br />

husbandry. <strong>The</strong> available evidence is comparatively scarce, since even important cash<br />

transactions did not have to be recorded in writing. We are, on the other hand, well<br />

informed about the wider background of this trade, since businessmen frequently had<br />

to form partnerships with colleagues to acquire the necessary capital for such ventures.<br />

Partnership contracts attest a wide range of different arrangements: joint ventures of<br />

partners equally sharing work, risk and profit are just as frequent as one-sided contracts<br />

with sleeping partners or ‘capitalists’ (not infrequently royal officials) who invested<br />

in the business of other (often younger) men. Such partnerships could exist for decades,<br />

only to be dissolved at the death of one of the partners; they could even be handed<br />

down to the heirs of their founders.<br />

<strong>The</strong> volume of domestic trade in primary goods cannot be quantified reliably, but<br />

it must have been significant. This is borne out by individual texts documenting<br />

very important transactions, by the evidence for large-scale cash crop agriculture, and<br />

by the fact that, in all likelihood, a numerically significant part of the urban population<br />

seems to have been dependent on a food-market for their livelihood (see below).<br />

International long-distance trade is even more difficult to get to grips with. <strong>The</strong> bestattested<br />

imported goods are slaves, iron, copper, wine, wood, alum and dyes (for the<br />

<strong>Babylonian</strong> textile industry) and prestige goods such as aromatics, scarabs and glass.<br />

Most of these came from the west. Babylonia exported slaves, barley, dates, wool and<br />

garments. It is likely that textiles were the most important export product, but this<br />

cannot be verified on the basis of the available sources. 16 <strong>The</strong> obvious monetisation<br />

of economic exchange in Babylonia means that much silver was coming into the<br />

country. <strong>The</strong> two main sources were trade and tribute, as well as booty taken by the<br />

Neo-<strong>Babylonian</strong> kings from the west, but it is impossible to tell which may have<br />

been more important. Under Achaemenid rule, taxes payable in silver caused much<br />

money to be withdrawn from circulation within Babylonia but, by and large, no clear<br />

deflationary tendencies are noticeable. This suggests that money was still flowing into<br />

the country; and in this period this must have been primarily a result of trade, government<br />

spending being of less importance under foreign rule.<br />

231

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!