25.03.2013 Views

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

The Babylonian World - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

— Power, economy and social organisation in Babylonia —<br />

<strong>The</strong>se so-called ‘house-born’ slaves could advance sometimes in their social position,<br />

and stipulations in the Old <strong>Babylonian</strong> laws concern their duties and their rights. In<br />

the case of people taken as prisoners of war and enslaved thereafter, a considerable<br />

number of them were transferred to the big institutions to serve as agricultural workers<br />

or in the army. In accordance with older customs, the females were often assigned<br />

to textile manufactures, at least in Old <strong>Babylonian</strong> Mari.<br />

Buying and selling slaves was a common practice in Mesopotamia. According to<br />

some authors chattel slavery is considered a precondition for the use of the term slave.<br />

However, the citizens from Babylon and of certain other cities enjoyed some protection<br />

against entering into chattel slavery (Stol 2004: 915). At least in theory, all slaves<br />

came from outside of Babylonia proper.<br />

<strong>The</strong> citizens at the upper end of the social ladder had various obligations towards<br />

the state. In return for their services, they received either prebend fields or rations.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y were termed awīlum, the Akkadian word for the ‘(male) human being’, and in<br />

the law texts the term is often translated as ‘free man’, ‘gentleman’, or the like,<br />

ignoring thus the obligatory ties this class of people had towards the state. <strong>The</strong><br />

members of this class possessed full rights and the state was responsible for their<br />

welfare. <strong>The</strong>y formed the backbone of the <strong>Babylonian</strong> society. <strong>The</strong>y often transferred<br />

their duties to other persons; then their so-called ilku-service was often performed by<br />

a class of people of lower social status, called musˇkēnum, roughly translated as<br />

‘commoner’. <strong>The</strong>y received various payments from the citizens for their services, such<br />

as subsistence fields (Stol 2004: 761). In later periods silver became the standard for<br />

such compensations (Stol 2004: 741f.). <strong>The</strong> commoners had no formal obligations<br />

towards the state, but they had also to look after themselves and possessed lesser<br />

rights. Especially in times of an economic crisis, these people suffered greatly. Whereas<br />

institutions provide a social net to ‘catch’ people under such circumstances, the<br />

musˇkēnum fell through the cracks (Stol 2004: 732f.). Even belonging to the class of<br />

slaves may sometimes have been better.<br />

It may, nevertheless, come as a surprise that such a social safety net existed at all.<br />

Old <strong>Babylonian</strong> documents give good evidence that the institutions provided for their<br />

members in case of need, rather in the sense of a social security. <strong>The</strong>re are records of<br />

silver expenditures or extra rations in cases of illness, such as a broken leg, or in times<br />

of hardship, e.g. following the death of a member of the family. Such expenditures<br />

are listed among other, ‘normal’ or regular expenditures that did not require any<br />

extra explanation (Breckwoldt 1995).<br />

ECONOMIC CRISIS<br />

Already in the planned economy of the third millennium, certain groups of people<br />

received their share of the profits made through their work. However, the amount of<br />

produce they had to deliver to the big institutions was fixed in advance and temporarily<br />

adjusted according to changing expectations and the needs of an always-demanding<br />

state. If, for one reason or another, a group of people could not meet the demands<br />

of the institution, the shortfall was entered in the institution’s accounts as a kind of<br />

debt, to be met in one of the following years. In the course of several ‘bad’ years<br />

the debts could accumulate to a considerable amount. With this concept of institutional<br />

debt and credit, it was just a small step further to introduce the concepts of interest<br />

283

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!