28.12.2013 Views

Theories of the Information Society, Third Edition - Cryptome

Theories of the Information Society, Third Edition - Cryptome

Theories of the Information Society, Third Edition - Cryptome

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

INFORMATION AND THE MARKET<br />

order. As such, it is regarded as vendible, subject to <strong>the</strong> price mechanism, and<br />

hence a commodity to be bought and sold by one party or ano<strong>the</strong>r. It is reasonable<br />

to ask why this should matter since no one, certainly not Herbert Schiller,<br />

suggests that information, still less ICTs, come free <strong>of</strong> cost.<br />

Much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> objection to commodification comes down to what Oscar Wilde<br />

disparagingly termed knowing ‘<strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> everything and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> nothing’.<br />

There is a lengthy tradition <strong>of</strong> thought, by no means all radical, that voices this<br />

concern about <strong>the</strong> limits <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price mechanism. For instance, in <strong>the</strong> early 1990s,<br />

a Conservative minister, David Mellor, warned against too strong an imposition<br />

<strong>of</strong> commercial practices on <strong>the</strong> arts when he advised his audience that <strong>the</strong>y might<br />

do well to remember that in ‘<strong>the</strong> long run a society is judged not so much by its<br />

economic achievements, but by its cultural ones’. This is a salutary reminder that<br />

we recollect <strong>the</strong> nineteenth century less for its cotton and coal barons, though<br />

<strong>the</strong>y ruled supreme in those days, than for its artists and architects. Mellor’s was<br />

a speech delivered during a period <strong>of</strong> enthusiastic and determined advancement<br />

<strong>of</strong> capitalist principles, when entrepreneurs and private enterprise were much<br />

praised, yet still a Cabinet member could warn <strong>of</strong> its limitations.<br />

None<strong>the</strong>less, in recent decades we have witnessed an accelerated commodification<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informational realm. More <strong>of</strong> this will be considered in <strong>the</strong><br />

following chapter, including in <strong>the</strong> realm <strong>of</strong> television where it is especially<br />

evident, but at this point we may also instance <strong>the</strong> heightened price valuation <strong>of</strong><br />

‘brands’ (de Chernatony and McDonald, 2003). Products still matter, <strong>of</strong> course,<br />

but <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> a brand, from <strong>the</strong> Nike swooshes to <strong>the</strong> Virgin label have developed<br />

an increased significance in recent years. Thus even British universities now<br />

assiduously market <strong>the</strong>ir brand, eager to recruit students from abroad since<br />

<strong>the</strong>y can be charged much more than domestic ones and <strong>the</strong> fees are lucrative.<br />

The process has extended even to <strong>the</strong> commodification <strong>of</strong> a name, famously so<br />

in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> footballer David Beckham whose transfer to Real Madrid from<br />

Manchester United owed much to <strong>the</strong> selling power <strong>of</strong> his name in <strong>the</strong> Far East<br />

promising increased merchandising opportunities. It is striking that nowadays<br />

such intangibles as a ‘name’ carry economic weight beyond <strong>the</strong> actual technical<br />

capabilities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> player.<br />

Accompanying this has been a heightened concern for intellectual property<br />

and its protection by way <strong>of</strong> copyright and patenting, processes that Lawrence<br />

Lessig (2000) regards as a form <strong>of</strong> enclosure (Boyle, 2002) – a drawing into market<br />

relationships arrangements that may once have been excluded. They are all<br />

dedicated to ensuring that <strong>the</strong> correct proprietor is identified and <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

information maximised. Consider, for example, <strong>the</strong> complaint <strong>of</strong> John Su<strong>the</strong>rland<br />

(1999) regarding <strong>the</strong> digitalisation <strong>of</strong> reviews and articles he has written in <strong>the</strong><br />

Times Literary Supplement and <strong>the</strong> Times Higher Education Supplement over many<br />

years. Previously, <strong>the</strong> pieces were hard-copy published, Su<strong>the</strong>rland received a fee<br />

for <strong>the</strong> job, and that was <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> matter. If readers wanted to consult his<br />

writings, <strong>the</strong>y ei<strong>the</strong>r bought or borrowed <strong>the</strong> original periodical or, if after an<br />

old edition, consulted it in an academic library where bound copies (or possibly<br />

micr<strong>of</strong>ilms) were stored. Digitalisation, however, makes <strong>the</strong> backlog readily accessible<br />

from anywhere to those with a subscription and communications facilities.<br />

144

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!