28.12.2013 Views

Theories of the Information Society, Third Edition - Cryptome

Theories of the Information Society, Third Edition - Cryptome

Theories of the Information Society, Third Edition - Cryptome

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

POST-INDUSTRIAL SOCIETY<br />

untenable and that it is possible to demonstrate that <strong>the</strong>re are identifiable<br />

continuities that have a systemic reach.<br />

But, before we proceed to <strong>the</strong>se more substantial arguments, <strong>the</strong>re is ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

reason to suspect <strong>the</strong> idea <strong>of</strong> a new ‘post-industrial’ era emerging. This may be<br />

explored by examining <strong>the</strong> reasons Bell <strong>of</strong>fers by way <strong>of</strong> explanation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transition<br />

from <strong>the</strong> old to <strong>the</strong> new regime. When we ask why <strong>the</strong>se changes occur,<br />

Bell appeals to arguments that are remarkably familiar in social science. Such is<br />

this intellectual conservatism that we have grounds to be sceptical about <strong>the</strong><br />

validity <strong>of</strong> his claim that a radically new system is emerging.<br />

Let me clarify this. As we have seen, <strong>the</strong> reason for change according to Bell<br />

is that increases in productivity allow employees to shift from agriculture and<br />

industry to services. Productivity increases come from technological innovations<br />

that gave us more food from fewer farmers and more goods from factories with<br />

fewer workers. As Bell says: ‘[T]echnology . . . is <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> increased productivity,<br />

and productivity has been <strong>the</strong> transforming fact <strong>of</strong> economic life’ (1973,<br />

p. 191). It is this productivity that lays <strong>the</strong> basis for PIS since its beneficence<br />

pays for all those service occupations.<br />

What is particularly noticeable about this is that it is a very familiar form <strong>of</strong><br />

sociological reasoning and, being an expression <strong>of</strong> technological determinism, one<br />

which is deeply suspect in social science. It carries two especially dubious implications:<br />

one, that technologies are <strong>the</strong> decisive agents <strong>of</strong> social change; two, that<br />

technologies are <strong>the</strong>mselves alo<strong>of</strong> from <strong>the</strong> social world, though <strong>the</strong>y have<br />

enormous social effects. Where, critics ask, are people, capital, politics, classes,<br />

interests in all <strong>of</strong> this (Webster and Robins, 1986, ch. 2)? Can it be seriously<br />

suggested that technologies are at once <strong>the</strong> motor <strong>of</strong> change and simultaneously<br />

untouched by social relations? Whatever happened to <strong>the</strong> values and powers that<br />

determine R&D budgets? To corporate priorities in investing in innovation? To<br />

government preferences for this project ra<strong>the</strong>r than for that one?<br />

More important than details <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> objection to technological determinism<br />

here is <strong>the</strong> need to appreciate fully <strong>the</strong> more general character <strong>of</strong> Bell’s intellectual<br />

conservatism. This old proposition, that technology is <strong>the</strong> driving force <strong>of</strong><br />

change (traceable through a lineage at least to Henri Saint-Simon and Auguste<br />

Comte writing during <strong>the</strong> early stages <strong>of</strong> industrialisation in <strong>the</strong> closing years <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> eighteenth century), is heavily criticised in virtually every sociology primer.<br />

Its deep-rootedness in <strong>the</strong> history <strong>of</strong> social thought really must lead one to query<br />

Bell’s assertion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> novelty <strong>of</strong> ‘post-industrialism’.<br />

Moreover, ano<strong>the</strong>r source <strong>of</strong> his views reinforces this suspicion. This is<br />

Bell’s indebtedness to Max Weber – a major founder <strong>of</strong> classical sociology who<br />

wrote in <strong>the</strong> late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industrial changes<br />

taking place around him – and in particular his interpretation <strong>of</strong> Weber as <strong>the</strong><br />

major thinker on ‘rationalisation’. Bell tells us that Weber thought ‘<strong>the</strong> master<br />

key <strong>of</strong> Western society was rationalisation’ (Bell, 1973, p. 67), which, in Bell’s<br />

terms, means <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> an ethos <strong>of</strong> ‘more for less’ or, less prosaically, ‘<strong>the</strong><br />

spread through law <strong>of</strong> a spirit <strong>of</strong> functional efficiency and measurement, <strong>of</strong> an<br />

“economising” attitude (maximisation, optimisation, least cost) towards not only<br />

material resources but all life’ (p. 67). Put o<strong>the</strong>rwise, <strong>the</strong> increase in productivity,<br />

44

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!