14.12.2012 Views

World agriculture towards 2030/2050: the 2012 revision - Fao

World agriculture towards 2030/2050: the 2012 revision - Fao

World agriculture towards 2030/2050: the 2012 revision - Fao

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

PROOF COPY<br />

Considering <strong>the</strong> projections that imply more than 3-fold increase in world economic<br />

activity in just 45 years, one cannot but pose <strong>the</strong> issue of limits imposed by natural resource<br />

constraints and <strong>the</strong> environment. The fact that those that make <strong>the</strong>se projections consider <strong>the</strong>m<br />

as possible outcomes, even in a scenario sense, suggests ei<strong>the</strong>r of two things: (a) that such<br />

constraints will not prove binding in <strong>the</strong> 45-year projection period, or (b) more likely, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

make <strong>the</strong> implicit assumption that, in time-honoured fashion, a more prosperous world will be<br />

finding ways around such constraints, as and when <strong>the</strong>y arise – a Julian Simon concept of<br />

economic progress (Simon, 1996).<br />

We cannot possibly examine <strong>the</strong>se aspects here, but certainly we shall have to address<br />

<strong>the</strong> issue whe<strong>the</strong>r agricultural resources, toge<strong>the</strong>r with prospective developments in<br />

technology and investments in <strong>the</strong> sector, are sufficient to meet <strong>the</strong> demands placed upon<br />

<strong>the</strong>m by a growing population and <strong>the</strong> growth of incomes and changes in diets <strong>towards</strong> more<br />

livestock products. The saving grace in <strong>the</strong> case of food is that consumption per capita is a<br />

largely bounded variable: incomes may continue growing but, beyond certain levels (when<br />

per capita food consumption approaches saturation) such income growth becomes largely<br />

irrelevant as it will not be generating additional pressures, at least not significant ones, on<br />

agricultural resources for increasing food production. Considering also that population growth<br />

will be slowing down, we can be more sanguine about absence of constraints to development<br />

arising from global agricultural resource scarcities for producing food than from o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

resources, e.g. energy and <strong>the</strong> environment. However, growth of total GDP becomes very<br />

relevant for pressures exerted on agricultural resources if, as is likely, it increases competition<br />

among <strong>agriculture</strong> and alternative (non-food production) uses of land and water, e.g. diversion<br />

to biofuels production, or to urban, industrial and infrastructure development.<br />

GDP projections used in this study<br />

Our projections of food demand are derived, as a first step, as functions of projected per<br />

capita GDPs, using different Engel functions for <strong>the</strong> different commodities and countries. The<br />

projected per capita GDPs are exogenous variables to our agricultural projections exercise and<br />

come from o<strong>the</strong>r sources that specialize in economy-wide analyses and modelling. The<br />

demand projections are subsequently modified, sometimes substantially, in <strong>the</strong> context of<br />

successive rounds of <strong>revision</strong>s for nutritional consistency and compatibility with “feasible”<br />

projected levels of production and trade for each commodity.<br />

We have traditionally depended on external sources for <strong>the</strong> GDP projections, usually<br />

from <strong>the</strong> <strong>World</strong> Bank. For <strong>the</strong> present study, <strong>the</strong> staff of <strong>the</strong> Development Prospects Group of<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>World</strong> Bank kindly made available one set of GDP projections related to <strong>the</strong>ir above<br />

mentioned work, though much more conservative than <strong>the</strong> one used in <strong>the</strong>ir paper for <strong>the</strong><br />

2009 Expert Group (van der Mensbrugghe et al., 2011). They are shown in Table 2.4: world<br />

GDP grows at 2.1 percent p.a., from 2005/07-<strong>2050</strong>; that of <strong>the</strong> developing countries (our<br />

definition used in this study) at 3.6 percent p.a. The differential growth rates will contribute<br />

<strong>towards</strong> convergence between per capita incomes in <strong>the</strong> developed and <strong>the</strong> developing<br />

countries. At present <strong>the</strong> average of <strong>the</strong> developed countries is nearly 12 times as high as that<br />

of <strong>the</strong> developing countries when GDP is measured in dollars at market exchange rates of<br />

2005/07. The ratio may be nearly halved by <strong>2050</strong>, i.e. decline to 6.3. The initial gap between<br />

developed and developing countries is much smaller if GDP is measured in dollars at PPP<br />

exchange rates. This we can measure for <strong>the</strong> historical data: <strong>the</strong> ratio of incomes in 2005/07 is<br />

5.9 ra<strong>the</strong>r than 11.9 (Table 2.4). However, as noted PPPs change as incomes of <strong>the</strong> low<br />

income countries grow faster than those of <strong>the</strong> high income countries and <strong>the</strong> distance<br />

between <strong>the</strong> two narrows: it follows that <strong>the</strong> ratio of incomes may be less than halved by <strong>2050</strong><br />

if incomes are measured at <strong>the</strong> PPPs that would prevail in <strong>2050</strong>.<br />

37

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!