11.08.2013 Views

Outdoor Lighting and Crime - Amper

Outdoor Lighting and Crime - Amper

Outdoor Lighting and Crime - Amper

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Marchant (2003) pointed out that the quantity called the odds ratio by Farrington <strong>and</strong> Welsh<br />

would be more correctly described as a cross-product ratio (CPR). He also showed that<br />

incorrect statistical treatment by Farrington <strong>and</strong> Welsh resulted in values of the CPR that were<br />

too large <strong>and</strong> confidence intervals that were too narrow. As with the errors described in Part<br />

1, the net effect is to increase the likelihood that the true value of the CPR is less than 1. Such<br />

a value would mean that crime increases with the amount of outdoor light, consistent with the<br />

observations described above. 38<br />

The idea that outdoor crime at night has a net positive direct connection with outdoor light<br />

levels may seem counter-intuitive, given the common experience that lighting tends to allay<br />

the fear of crime. If true, it would imply a predominance of daytime crime over night crime,<br />

as actually happens with residential burglaries in the USA. Research would be required to<br />

establish the relative contributions of light <strong>and</strong> social factors in determining such<br />

predominances, but some general observations are possible here.<br />

If all crime did decrease steeply without temporal displacement as a direct effect of increased<br />

lighting, <strong>and</strong> if night <strong>and</strong> day opportunities for crime were equal, turning night into day with<br />

artificial light could be expected to do no more than halve the overall crime rate. But some<br />

crimes are generally committed indoors (eg ‘white-collar’ crime). Any direct facilitating<br />

influence of outdoor lighting at night on such crimes does not seem credible. Therefore, for<br />

all kinds of crime aggregated, the maximum possible decrease accompanying the installation<br />

of intense outdoor lighting, according to existing belief, would appear to be limited to less<br />

than a factor of two.<br />

Ambient outdoor light levels at night in many parts of even the world’s most brightly lit cities<br />

are still well short of daylight values in general. The actual crime rate increases shown in<br />

Figures 1, 2, 3 <strong>and</strong> 4 generally well exceed a factor of two over two decades or so. A positive<br />

(adverse) direct effect of lighting on crime is in accordance with the long-term direction of<br />

change in observed crime but the national increases in crime rate appear too large to be<br />

accounted for by direct effects of lighting increases. The crime-changing effects of lighting<br />

claimed by Painter <strong>and</strong> Farrington (1997, 1999a,b) do include what are here called indirect<br />

effects <strong>and</strong> could account for the magnitude of the observed changes, except that they are<br />

clearly in the wrong direction. Any direct effects of lighting on crime appear to be swamped<br />

by other processes.<br />

Excluding temporal displacement, a direct daytime effect on crime, increase or decrease, by<br />

what some commentators have called ‘switched-off outdoor lighting’ can hardly be regarded<br />

as anything but unlikely if not far-fetched. Nevertheless, there are known environmental <strong>and</strong><br />

socio-economic effects on crime incidence, such as seasonal effects (Baumer <strong>and</strong> Wright 39<br />

1996, Jochelson 1997, DCPC 2001) or, say, the effects of wars or overseas financial changes<br />

on international tourist numbers <strong>and</strong> hence numbers of tourists available to be crime victims.<br />

These fit the above definition of indirect effects. Indirect social or economic effects of<br />

38 In Section 5.5.2 of Part 1, the reciprocal of the ‘odds ratio’ was proposed as a more useful<br />

measure called the ‘crime ratio’ or similar. <strong>Crime</strong> increase with added light would thus give a<br />

crime ratio of more than 1.<br />

39 Baumer <strong>and</strong> Wright cited 36 references on the seasonal variation of crime in refuting a<br />

claim by Farrell <strong>and</strong> Pease (1994) that there was almost no published work on the subject.<br />

38

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!