07.03.2017 Views

POLLINATORS POLLINATION AND FOOD PRODUCTION

individual_chapters_pollination_20170305

individual_chapters_pollination_20170305

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

THE ASSESSMENT REPORT ON <strong>POLLINATORS</strong>, <strong>POLLINATION</strong> <strong>AND</strong> <strong>FOOD</strong> <strong>PRODUCTION</strong><br />

sustainability of pollination services should be evaluated<br />

regarding, not only its impact on consumption path or the<br />

welfare of a typical individual, but in order to maintain these<br />

life opportunities.<br />

1.2 Linking economic values with<br />

pollination<br />

The economic literature systematically links valuation with<br />

decision, public awareness and policy-making. Indeed, the<br />

conceptual framework of economic valuation is designed for<br />

collecting and organizing information toward hierarchizing<br />

and selecting choice options (for instance, agriculture policy<br />

or biodiversity strategy; Costanza et al., 2014). However,<br />

there apparently are broader motives behind economic<br />

valuations, and some authors have suggested that the link<br />

between valuations and decision-making was more related<br />

to general advocacy than to providing technical information<br />

(Laurans et al., 2013; Laurans and Mermet, 2014).<br />

replacement, see Allsopp et al., 2008) and the few published<br />

results appear quite sensitive to the valuation method.<br />

The design and assessment of cost-effective policies<br />

and action can be of real importance, but enlighten only<br />

a framework for a least-cost approach for some policy<br />

target (cost-efficiency) without demonstrating that it is the<br />

best social choice (the gain are not necessary larger than<br />

the costs). For example, the market for colony rental for<br />

almond orchards in California (Klein et al., 2012) might be the<br />

simplest way to meet the needs of large-scale monocropping<br />

landscapes. However, the pollinator shortage might also<br />

be solved if agricultural landscapes were to become more<br />

heterogeneous (Hussain and Miller, 2014), if producers<br />

switched to crops less dependent on pollinators or even<br />

developing artificial pollination techniques, but this is in most<br />

cases highly speculative. Economic valuation can assist in<br />

this process by identifying not only the most cost-effective<br />

solution but the fairest and most sustainable ones as well.<br />

1.2.1 Understanding the importance of<br />

what is at stake<br />

There is growing evidence of insect pollinator decline<br />

in many regions and its consequences (e.g., fruit and<br />

vegetable production decline in quantity and/or quality)<br />

are occurring, but building indicators of these changes<br />

is difficult and the result can be controversial or of limited<br />

social impact if expressed in a metric understood only by<br />

scientist and experts. The first interest of estimating the<br />

value of pollination service or the cost of pollinator decline<br />

is certainly to raise awareness on their importance for our<br />

societies, and to offer a clear and simple argument to help<br />

policy-makers to make choice about the opportunity to<br />

design and implement appropriate measures. Estimating<br />

the cost of pollinators’ decline in economic terms allows<br />

the comparison of the result to other issues and, more<br />

importantly, to the cost of the remedies that can be<br />

proposed to this problem. In many cases, a precise study of<br />

the local variations in value indicators will be more helpful for<br />

decision making than global information.<br />

SECTION 2. METHODS FOR<br />

ASSESSING THE ECONOMIC<br />

CONSEQUENCES OF<br />

POLLINATOR GAINS <strong>AND</strong><br />

LOSSES<br />

A number of methods have been used throughout the<br />

published literature to quantify the economic consequences<br />

of pollinator gains and (most often) losses. The following<br />

section reviews the principle details of each of these<br />

methods, focusing on what it measures (price or value<br />

and of what specifically), an overview of the methodology<br />

involved, it’s strengths and weaknesses, under what<br />

situations it is suitable to use and what data is required.<br />

Key examples of each method (some of which are reviewed<br />

in detail in Section 7) are provided for interested readers.<br />

Table 4.2 summarises these methods for ease of reference.<br />

2.1 Price Aggregation<br />

217<br />

4. ECONOMIC VALUATION OF POLLINATOR GAINS<br />

<strong>AND</strong> LOSSES<br />

1.2.2 Defining hierarchies, priorities and<br />

choices<br />

Comparing the cost of declining pollinators to the cost<br />

of implementing alternative options in behaviours and<br />

solutions is clearly a difficult task. The main difficulty is<br />

usually to assess the cost of moving away from the current<br />

policies and behaviours. However, drawing a clear picture<br />

of alternative practice and organization can be a challenge<br />

as well. There is in fact little literature that directly offers<br />

estimates of such change (for an analysis based on cost of<br />

2.1.1 Aggregate crop price<br />

What it Measures: The total market price of animal<br />

pollinated crop production.<br />

Methodology: This method assumes that production of<br />

all animal pollinated crops would cease in the absence of<br />

pollination services and therefore equates the total sale price<br />

of all crops that benefit from animal pollination, with the<br />

value of pollination services themselves.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!