17.01.2013 Views

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

220 5. Empirical issues for the collective model<br />

We thus conclude that the partials of ρ with respect to income and distribution<br />

factor are identifiable.<br />

Finally, the first two equations of (5.25) and of (5.27) give respectively:<br />

∂ρ<br />

∂wb = ∂la /∂wb ∂la ∂ρ<br />

/∂y ∂y = ∂la /∂wb ∂la F<br />

/∂y<br />

b<br />

F b and<br />

− F a<br />

∂ρ<br />

∂wa = ∂lb /∂wa ∂lb µ<br />

1 −<br />

/∂y<br />

∂ρ<br />

<br />

= −<br />

∂y<br />

∂la /∂wb ∂la F<br />

/∂y<br />

a<br />

F b − F a (5.29)<br />

Theconclusionisthusthatall partial derivatives of the sharing rule can be<br />

exactly recovered from the observation of the two labor supply functions.<br />

From the sole observation of labor supplies, one can recover the impact<br />

of wages, non labor income and distribution factors on the sharing rule.<br />

Finally, the cross derivative restrictions generate additional testable predictions.<br />

The reader may realize that this conclusion is by no means surprising;<br />

indeed, it stems from the general results presented in the previous<br />

subsection.<br />

The sharing rule itself is identified up to an additive constant; that constant<br />

cannot be identified unless either all commodities are assignable or<br />

individual preferences are known (for instance, from data on singles). To<br />

see why, take labor supply functions la and lb that satisfy (5.23) and (5.24)<br />

for some sharing rule ρ and some Marshallian demands ˜l s derived from<br />

individual utilities us ,s = a, b. Now,forsomeconstantK, define ρK,ua K<br />

and u b K by:<br />

¡ ¢ a b<br />

ρK w ,w ,y,z =<br />

¡ ¢ a b<br />

ρ w ,w ,y,z + K<br />

u a K (l a ,C a ) = u a (l a ,C a ¡ b b<br />

l ,C<br />

− K)<br />

¢ = u b ¡ l b ,C b + K ¢<br />

u b K<br />

It is easy to check that the Marshallian demands derived from ρK,ua K and<br />

ub K satisfy (5.23) and (5.24). The intuition is illustrated in Figure 5.1 in the<br />

case of a. Switching from ρ and ua to ρK and ua K does two things. First,<br />

the sharing rule, therefore the intercept of the budget constraint, is shifted<br />

downward by K; second, all indifference curves are also shifted downward<br />

by the same amount. When only labor supply (on the horizontal axis) is<br />

observable, these models are empirically indistinguishable.<br />

Note, however, that the models are also welfare equivalent (that is, the<br />

constant is ‘irrelevant’), in the sense definedinsection3.3of chapter 4:<br />

changing the constant affects neither the comparative statics nor the welfare<br />

analysis derived from the model. Technically, the collective indirect<br />

utility of each member is the same in both models; one can readily check<br />

that the two models generate the same level of utility for each spouse. In<br />

theend,theoptimalidentification strategy depends on the question under<br />

consideration. If one want to formulate welfare judgments, collective indirect<br />

utilities are sufficient, and they can be recovered without additional

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!