17.01.2013 Views

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

234 5. Empirical issues for the collective model<br />

either spouse’s wage rate reduces their share of the nonlabor income,<br />

which in turn increases their labor supply through an income effect.<br />

Indeed, both men’s and women’s labor supply elasticities with respect<br />

to nonlabor income are negative and significant.<br />

Recent empirical developments involving cooperative models of labor<br />

supply include Donni (2003), which generalizes the standard approach to<br />

corner solutions and non-linear budget constraints, and Blundell, <strong>Chiappori</strong>,<br />

Magnac and Meghir (2007), who consider a model in which female<br />

labor supply is continuous whereas male labor supply is discrete; they show<br />

that the sharing rule can equally be recovered in this case. Moreau and<br />

Donni (2002) also introduce distribution factors, applied to French data,<br />

and take into account the non-linearity of taxation. Other empirical analyzes<br />

include Bloemen (2009), Clark, Couprie and Sofer (2004) and Vermeulen<br />

(2005) on Dutch, British and Belgian data respectively.<br />

In a series of recently published papers, several authors apply the collective<br />

model to welfare issues, including the impact of changes in the<br />

tax/benefit system,indifferent European countries. The basic methodology,<br />

as described in Vermeulen et al (2006), presents interesting features.<br />

One is its scope: the approach addresses standard problems of welfare analysis<br />

of labor supply, such as non linear taxation, non convex budget sets<br />

and discrete participation decisions, within a collective framework. In addition,<br />

individual preferences are more general than in the standard collective<br />

model of labor supply (<strong>Chiappori</strong> 1988, 1992) in the sense that<br />

they allow for interactions between individual leisures (that is, the marginal<br />

utility of a spouse’s leisure is a function of the other spouse’s labor<br />

supply). Since individual leisures are treated as public goods, the standard<br />

identification results do not apply. The identification strategy relies on a<br />

different assumption - namely, that the ‘direct’ trade-off between individual<br />

leisure and consumption (disregarding the impact of the spouse’s leisure)<br />

is identical for singles and married individuals, and can therefore be directly<br />

estimated from the labor supply of singles; of course the additional,<br />

‘external’ effect of one spouse’s leisure on the other’s utility can only be<br />

estimated from the sample of married couples. This approach allows to calibrate<br />

a collective model that can then be used for welfare analysis. Myck<br />

et al. (2006) uses this framework to analyze the impact of a recent welfare<br />

reform in the UK, namely the introduction of the Working Families’ Tax<br />

Credit (WFTC). In particular, they consider two hypothetical versions of<br />

the reform: one in which the recipient remains the main carer (as for the<br />

previous <strong>Family</strong> Credit), and another in which the benefit ispaidtothe<br />

main earner. The model allows to predict the impact of each version on the<br />

spouses’ respective Pareto weights, and the corresponding labor supply responses;<br />

they conclude that, indeed, the two versions have different impact<br />

on individual labor supplies and ultimately welfares. Similar studies have<br />

been undertaken in various countries, including Belgium, France, Germany,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!