17.01.2013 Views

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

8. Sharing the gains from marriage 351<br />

exceeding y rises for all y, so that women become more similar to men in<br />

terms of their income, as we observe in practice. Such an upward first order<br />

shift in the distribution of female income affects the matching functions in<br />

exactly the same way as a marginal increase in the female/male sex ratio.<br />

Thus, if all men maintain their income, they all become better off. Similarly,<br />

any woman who would maintain her income would become worse off. This<br />

remark should however be interpreted with care, because it is obviously<br />

impossible for all women to maintain their income: when the distribution<br />

of female incomes shifts to the right, some (and possibly all) females must<br />

have higher income. In particular, those women who maintain their relative<br />

rank (quantile) in the distribution will maintain their position in the<br />

competition for men, and will be matched with a husband with the same<br />

income as before. Such women will be better off, as a consequence of the<br />

increase in their own income.<br />

As a special case, consider the linear shift case described above; to keep<br />

things simple, assume moreover that β =0.Suppose,now,thattheincome<br />

of every woman is inflated by some common factor k>1 and consider<br />

a married couple with initial incomes (x, y). After the shift, the partners<br />

remain married but the wife’s income is boosted to ky while the husband’s<br />

income remains equal to x. Ifuk and vk denote the new individual utilities,<br />

we have from (8.25) and (8.24):<br />

vk = K + kα<br />

H (ky + x) and (8.30)<br />

kα +1<br />

uk = K 0 + 1<br />

H (ky + x)<br />

kα +1<br />

Differentiating in k around k =1gives:<br />

∂vk<br />

∂k =<br />

α<br />

αy<br />

2 H (y + x)+<br />

(α +1) α +1 H 0 (y + x) and<br />

∂uk<br />

∂k<br />

=<br />

α<br />

y<br />

− 2 H (y + x)+<br />

(α +1) α +1 H 0 (y + x) (8.31)<br />

One can readily check that both changes are positive (for the second one,<br />

it stems from the convexity of H). We conclude that the shift has two impacts.<br />

First, the increase in total income generates some additional surplus<br />

(theterminyH 0 (y + x)), which is shared between spouse in proportion of<br />

their respective incomes (that is 1 and α). In addition, a redistribution is<br />

triggered by the shift. Specifically, since the wife’s share of total income is<br />

increased, so is her consumption; the husband therefore transfers to his wife<br />

an amount equal to a fraction α/ (α +1) 2 of total surplus. One can readily<br />

check that the transfer is proportionally larger for wealthier couples, since<br />

the ratio H (y + x) / (y + x) increases with (y + x) due to the convexity of<br />

H.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!