17.01.2013 Views

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

Pierre André Chiappori (Columbia) "Family Economics" - Cemmap

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

1. Facts 25<br />

a sharp decrease. This is consistent with Figure 1.30 which shows a peak<br />

in fertility for mothers born in the mid-1930’s; this is the baby boom generation.<br />

The median age at first marriage has also increased at the same<br />

period suggesting fewer "forced marriages" (see Michael, 1988 and Goldin<br />

and Katz, 2002).<br />

Figure 1.33 presents evidence on completed fertility for a cross-section<br />

of six western European countries for women born between 1931 and 1967.<br />

In common with the USA, all of theses countries display a falling pattern<br />

from the mid-1930’s, although the US has a much higher value in the early<br />

years (3.1 as compared to 2.65 for the highest European values). Thus all<br />

these countries indicate a ‘baby-bust’ even though the trends show significant<br />

differences across countries. For example, Italy has the lowest values<br />

throughout this period with a steady decline from 2.3 to 1.5 children per<br />

women. In contrast, the Netherlands starts off with a high value of 2.6 and<br />

falls quickly by about 0.7 children in 1946 and then falls much more slowly<br />

over the next twenty years by about 0.2 children. Most dramatic is the case<br />

of Spain which has the highest value in the early 1940’s (at 2.6 children per<br />

woman) and one of the lowest 25 years latest (at 1.6).<br />

The timing of children is also of interest. In Figures 1.34 and 1.35 we<br />

show the timing of first marriage and first birth for the same countries<br />

as in Figure 1.33. There is a clear relationship between reduced fertility<br />

and the delay in marriage. On the average, age of first child is only two<br />

years after year of marriage (28 and 26, respectively for the latest cohort<br />

born in 1963). In these figures, marriage does not include cohabitation. In<br />

most countries the latter is low for women born before 1960 but for some<br />

countries there is considerable cohabitation. For example, the dramatic rise<br />

in the Danish age at first marriage largely reflects the fact that marriage<br />

before the birth of a child is increasingly rare amongst younger cohorts.<br />

1.4.2 Children under different household arrangements<br />

One consequence of the increasing marital turnover is the sharp rise in the<br />

number of children who live in single parent and step parent households<br />

(see Table 1.16). In the US, 2005, 68 percent of children less than 18 years<br />

old lived with two parents (including step parents), 23 percent lived only<br />

with their mother and 5 percent lived only with their father whilst the rest<br />

lived in households with neither parent present. The impact of living with<br />

single parents on the children depends on the amount of transfers between<br />

unmarried parents. Generally, such transfers are small with a substantial<br />

proportion of eligible mothers receiving no transfer at all. Only about half<br />

of eligible women receive any child support and when a transfer is received<br />

it is about 20 percent of the mother’s income (see Table 1.17 and Figure<br />

1.36). The consequence is that divorced mothers have less than half of the<br />

family income of married mothers and, therefore, children living with single<br />

mothers are often in poverty. The impact of marital turnover on children is

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!