13.02.2013 Views

BOOKS OF RtfiDIfGS - PAHO/WHO

BOOKS OF RtfiDIfGS - PAHO/WHO

BOOKS OF RtfiDIfGS - PAHO/WHO

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

- 354 -<br />

Application of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Health Services /<br />

pd~cies (2, 3, 34). There is controversy regarding which imperfectiona to allow for and<br />

how to allow for themn Another reason for differences of opinion, as Musgrave (35)<br />

o~ua cles, is the saitce of financing-private consumption or investment. Still another<br />

reason for differences of opinion is a value judgment: whether the proper measure of tho<br />

dLcount rate for public projects is the opportunity cost of capital in the private sector,<br />

or, to the contrary, whether it is the social rate of time preference. The private rate may<br />

be high, well above 10 per cent, particulady when allowance is made for the corporation<br />

income tax of 50 per cent (36). The social rate of time preference is usually much lower,<br />

based on a longer time horizon or greater readiness by the community acting together<br />

than by individuals to postpone gratification in favor of future generations. The social<br />

rate, which has been justified in terms of future risk and uncertainty, probability of<br />

personal survival, and the diminishing marginal utility of additional income or<br />

consumption as per capita income grows over time, is not a number that we know how to<br />

ascertain empirically (34). Accordingly, still another procedure, which combines private<br />

opportunity cost and social time preference, is also not measurable.<br />

In practice, the agencies of the federal government have employed a wide range of<br />

discount rates, usually without giving a reason (37). Nevertheless, the consequences of<br />

choosing a high or a low discount rate are clear. A low discount rate favors projects or<br />

programs with benefits accruing in the distant future. In effect, as Boulding (38) has<br />

suggested, a high interest rate favors the aged and a low one favors the middle aged. When<br />

a project or program is short-lived, with both benefits and costs concentrated in the near<br />

future, the choice of discount rate is of minor or no consequence; indeed, for a<br />

short-lived program discounting may be dispensed with. Some economists are averse to<br />

selecting a particular discount rate, on the ground that they are in no position to choose<br />

between generations (13, p. 57). The tendency is to display calculations of the present<br />

values of benefits and costs under two or more discount rates. It seems to me that such<br />

alternative calculations do not afford helpful guidance to the policy maker, unless he is<br />

advised when to employ one or the other.<br />

Even in the present state of the controversy there may be some merit to employing a<br />

single number for all public projects or for all public human investment projects. The<br />

combined method, recommended by a panel of consultants to the Bureau of the Budget<br />

in 1961 (39), and subsequently developed by Feldstein (40), can furnish an adequate<br />

rationale even though it does not yet yield a specific number. Such a number admittedly<br />

would be arbitrary, a reflection of value judgment (2). Henderson (34) reports that the<br />

French have adopted a centrally determined rate of discount of 7 per cent, to be applied<br />

to all public enterprises. This rate is higher than that encountered in many Ame~ican<br />

cost-benefit studies.<br />

APPLICATIONS <strong>OF</strong> COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS TO THE HEALTH FIELD<br />

The health services literature contains many affirmations of the importance of<br />

cost-benefit analysis for improving the allocation of resources to and within the health<br />

field. It may prove to be a source of astonishment that relatively few complete<br />

cost-benefit studies of health programs have been carried out. Perhaps it is appropriate<br />

that fewer cost-benefit studies have been performed than advocated. Where the am is to<br />

minimize the cost of producing a given good or service, or even of constructing a hospital<br />

of specified size and with suitable appurtenances, the apparatus of cost-benefit analysis is<br />

superfluous (33). It then suffices to compare unit costs.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!