13.02.2013 Views

BOOKS OF RtfiDIfGS - PAHO/WHO

BOOKS OF RtfiDIfGS - PAHO/WHO

BOOKS OF RtfiDIfGS - PAHO/WHO

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

- 358<br />

Application of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Health Sevmic /<br />

1. Our ordinary concern is with loss in earnings, not income. The latter includue<br />

income from property.<br />

2. Consumption by survivors is no longer subtracted from gross earnings in order to<br />

artive at net earnings. Viewed prospectively, everybody is a member of society, including<br />

the patient (54).<br />

3. The value of housewives' services is recognized, despite the fact that such services<br />

are not traded in the market and are omitted from the GNP. Weisbrod (13, pp. 114-119)<br />

developed and applied a complex method for measuring the cost of a substitute<br />

housekeeper, but subsequent writers have followed Kuznets (55) in employing a simpler<br />

approach, putting the value of the services of a housewife at the level of earnings of a<br />

full-time domestic servant. To employ a single number is the more practical procedure by<br />

far. The magnitude of that number is a separate question, however. It is increasingly<br />

evident that the value given by the earnings of a domestic servant is not adequate (56).<br />

Thus, the accepted value of the housewife's contribution would increase substantially if<br />

day care centers for working women were expanded at public cost.<br />

An alternative approach is to value the housewife's contribution at the opportunity<br />

cost of her staying out of the labor force (45). Implementation of this approach is<br />

impeded by two considerations (57). First, the method is complicated, since values would<br />

vary with the individual housewife's educational attainments, type of occupation, amount<br />

of job experience, full- or part-time employment status, etc. Second, nonpecuniary<br />

factors, which certainly influence the labor force participation rates of women, are<br />

difficult to measure and may behave erratically. When total family income permits, the<br />

pecuniary opportunity cost of the wife's staying home has been known to be as low as<br />

zero or even negative.<br />

4. The employment rate has been typically taken at 96 per cent, or an overall level of<br />

4 per cent unemployment at the level of "full" employment (44). In the 1970s the<br />

magnitude of this rate is at issue. Whatever the magnitude, Mushkin's argument is<br />

accepted that the health services system should not be charged with failures by the<br />

economy to provide jobs to all who seek them (41, 58).<br />

What is often not taken into account is the tendency for persons rehabilitated after<br />

serious illness or injury to find fewer job opportunities than persons who have remained<br />

healthy and on the job. In my study of syphilis (45), 1 recognized the loss of earnings due<br />

to the "stigma" attached to this and similar diseases. When prevention is feasible, it seems<br />

appropriate to assign to it an extra weight or bonus for this reason.<br />

5. Calculations of indirect benefits rest on the implicit assumption that the life<br />

expectancies of cohorts of potential survivors are known. Usually standard life tables are<br />

employed, separately for men and women. For diseases of low frequency it seems<br />

reasonable to disregard any effect on the total death rate occasioned by the deletion of a<br />

particular cause of death. For major diseases the problem is important, although simple<br />

deletion may be incorrect. As Weisbrod (13, pp. 34-35) recognized more than a decade<br />

ago, survivors who have avoided a particular cause of death may have a higher or lower<br />

susceptibility to other, competing causes of death. I compared the effects of simply<br />

deieting heart disease as a cause of death on life expectancy and on work-life expectancy.<br />

The former was large-1 1 to 12 years-and the latter was small-less than a year (46). For<br />

a disease with heavier impact at the younger ages, the effect on work-life expectancy<br />

would be relatively larger, and correspondingly greater attention would have to be paid to<br />

the effect of competing causes of death.<br />

J

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!