10.07.2015 Views

IPCC_Managing Risks of Extreme Events.pdf - Climate Access

IPCC_Managing Risks of Extreme Events.pdf - Climate Access

IPCC_Managing Risks of Extreme Events.pdf - Climate Access

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Chapter 6National Systems for <strong>Managing</strong> the <strong>Risks</strong> from <strong>Climate</strong> <strong>Extreme</strong>s and DisastersTable 6-2 | Government liabilities and disaster risk. Modified from Polackova Brixi andMody (2002).LiabilitiesExplicit: Governmentliability recognized bylaw or contractImplicit: A ‘moral’obligation <strong>of</strong> thegovernmentDirect: obligation inany eventForeign and domesticsovereign borrowing,expenditures by budget lawand budget expendituresFuture recurrent costs <strong>of</strong>public investment projects,pensions, and health careexpenditureContingent: obligation ifa particular event occursState guarantees for nonsovereignborrowing andpublic and private sectorentities, reconstruction <strong>of</strong>public infrastructureDefault <strong>of</strong> sub-nationalgovernment as public orprivate entities provide disasterreliefConsequently, a risk-neutral stance in dealing with catastrophic risk(implying that the consideration <strong>of</strong> risk broadly in terms <strong>of</strong> means – thestatistical expectation – is sufficient) may not be suitable for exposeddeveloping countries with limited diversification <strong>of</strong> their economies orsmall tax bases. Accordingly, assessing and managing risks over thewhole spectrum <strong>of</strong> probabilities is gaining momentum (Cardenas et al.,2007; Cummins and Mahul, 2009). As the Organization <strong>of</strong> American Statessuggests: “Government decisions should be based on the opportunitycosts to society <strong>of</strong> the resources invested in the project and on the loss<strong>of</strong> economic assets, functions and products. In view <strong>of</strong> the responsibilityvested in the public sector for the administration <strong>of</strong> scarce resources,and considering issues such as fiscal debt, trade balances, incomedistribution, and a wide range <strong>of</strong> other economic and social, andpolitical concerns, governments should not act risk-neutral” (OAS,1991). Also, in more developed economies, less-pronounced but stillconsiderable effects imposed by events linked to climate variability canbe identified. This has been shown by the Austrian political and fiscalcrisis in the aftermath <strong>of</strong> large-scale flooding that led to billions <strong>of</strong>Euros in losses in 2002 (Mechler et al., 2010).Budget and resource planning for extremes is not an easy proposition.Governments commonly plan and budget for direct liabilities, that is,liabilities that manifest themselves through certain and annually recurrentevents. Those liabilities are <strong>of</strong> explicit (as recognized by law or contract),or implicit nature (moral obligations) (see Table 6-2). Yet, governmentsare not good at planning for contingencies even for probable events, letalone improbable events. Explicit, contingent liabilities deal with thereconstruction <strong>of</strong> infrastructure destroyed by events, whereas implicitobligations are associated with providing relief – commonly consideredas a moral liability for governments (Polackova Brixi and Mody, 2002).In many countries, governments do not explicitly plan for contingentliabilities, and rely on reallocating their resources following disastersand raising capital from domestic and international donations to meetinfrastructure reconstruction needs and costs.More recently, some developing and transition countries that face largecontingent liabilities in the aftermath <strong>of</strong> extreme events and associatedfinancial gaps have begun to plan for and consider contingent naturalevents (also see Section 6.5.3). Mexico, Colombia, and many Caribbeancountries now include contingent liabilities in their budgetary processand eventually even transfer some <strong>of</strong> these risks (Cardenas et al., 2007;Linnerooth-Bayer and Mechler, 2007; Cummins and Mahul, 2009; seeBox 6-3). Similarly, many countries have also started to focus onimproving human development conditions as an adaptation strategy forclimate change and extreme events, particularly with the help <strong>of</strong>international agencies such as the World Bank. These deliberations areReduceVulnerabilityReduce <strong>Risks</strong>Reduce Hazardsand Exposure<strong>Risks</strong> AcceptanceThresholdPool, Transfer, andShare <strong>Risks</strong>Manage Residual <strong>Risks</strong> and UncertaintiesPrepare andRespond EffectivelyIncrease Capacity toCope with “Surprises”• Poverty reduction• Health improvements• <strong>Access</strong> to services andproductive assetsenhanced• Livelihood diversification• <strong>Access</strong> todecisionmakingincreased• Community securityimproved• Mainstream riskmanagement intodevelopment processes• Building codes andretr<strong>of</strong>itting• Defensive infrastructureand environmentalbuffers• Land use planning• Catchment and otherecosystem management• Incentive mechanismsfor individual actions toreduce exposure• Mutual and reservefunds• Financial insurance• Social networks andsocial capital• Alternative forms <strong>of</strong>risk transfer• Early warning andcommunication• Evacuation plan• Humanitarian: reliefsupplies• Post-disaster livelihoodsupport and recovery• Flexibility indecisionmaking• Adaptive learning andmanagement• Improved knowledgeand skills• Systems transformationover timeFigure 6-3 | Complementary response measures for observed and projected disaster risks supported by respective institutional and individual capacity for making informed decisions.361

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!