29.12.2016 Views

ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT

2hzAyD3

2hzAyD3

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

But these efforts left significant gaps even for children. They left even larger<br />

gaps for adults. Prior to the ACA, most state Medicaid programs did not<br />

cover adults without children, no matter how low their incomes, and the<br />

median state only covered working parents with incomes below 61 percent<br />

of the Federal Poverty Level (Heberlein, Brooks, and Alker 2013). As a<br />

result, low- and moderate-income non-elderly adults were by far the age and<br />

income group most likely to lack health insurance, as illustrated in Panel B<br />

of Figure 4-3.<br />

Failures of the Individual Health Insurance Market<br />

In addition to the affordability challenges described above, many<br />

uninsured Americans faced an additional barrier: the dysfunction of the<br />

individual health insurance market. While most non-elderly individuals<br />

had access to coverage through an employer, it was far from universal, even<br />

at relatively high income levels, as depicted in Figure 4-4. Retirees, many<br />

students, the self-employed, people working part-time due to family or other<br />

obligations, and the unemployed were all particularly likely to lack access to<br />

coverage through the workplace, as were individuals who happened to work<br />

at smaller firms or in industries where insurance coverage was not commonly<br />

offered. These individuals, if they did not qualify for public programs,<br />

had no choice but to turn to the individual market.<br />

The fundamental flaw of the pre-ACA individual health insurance<br />

market was that, unlike the employer market, the individual market lacked<br />

a mechanism for forming broad pools that included both relatively healthy<br />

and relatively sick individuals. The employer market forms broad pools by<br />

taking advantage of the fact that people are matched to employers based on<br />

a wide variety of factors, many of which are only loosely related to health status.<br />

In addition, employers typically cover around three-quarters of the premium,<br />

ensuring participation by a broad cross-section of their workforces,<br />

including both healthier and sicker workers (KFF/HRET 2016). Insurers<br />

offering coverage through employers can therefore be confident that their<br />

products will attract a balanced pool of healthier and sicker enrollees. As a<br />

result, their economic incentives generally drive them to design products<br />

that maximize the well-being of the pool as a whole.<br />

By contrast, insurers in the individual market had to contend with the<br />

possibility of “adverse selection,” the tendency of people with greater health<br />

care needs—and thus higher costs to insurers—to prefer more generous<br />

insurance coverage. Insurers’ concerns that they would attract an adversely<br />

selected pool drove them to engage in a wide range of practices aimed at<br />

discouraging enrollment by sicker individuals. These practices kept the<br />

individual market from performing the core functions of a health insurance<br />

204 | Chapter 4

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!