29.12.2016 Views

ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT

2hzAyD3

2hzAyD3

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

more to cover Medicare patients than it would have cost to cover the same<br />

patient in traditional Medicare (MedPAC 2009). To do so, the ACA phased<br />

in changes to the “benchmarks” used to determine payments to Medicare<br />

Advantage plans. These provisions have taken effect without adverse effects<br />

on the premiums or availability of Medicare Advantage plans, consistent<br />

with the view that pre-ACA payment rates were excessive. Access to<br />

Medicare Advantage plans remains essentially universal among Medicare<br />

beneficiaries, and the share of Medicare beneficiaries enrolled in a Medicare<br />

Advantage plan has risen from 24 percent in 2010 to a projected 32 percent<br />

in 2017, while average premiums are estimated to have fallen by 13 percent<br />

from 2010 through 2017 (CMS 2016b).<br />

Reforming the Structure of Medicare’s Payment Systems<br />

A second approach to increasing the value produced by the health<br />

care delivery system is to improve the structure of the payment systems that<br />

public health care programs and private insurers use to pay medical providers.<br />

Historically, the U.S. health care system has been dominated by “fee-forservice”<br />

payment systems in which medical providers are paid separately for<br />

each individual service they deliver, like an office visit, a diagnostic test, or<br />

a hospital stay.<br />

Fee-for-service payment undermines the efficiency and quality of<br />

patient care in three important ways. First, fee-for-service payment encourages<br />

providers to deliver more services than necessary since each additional<br />

service translates into additional revenue. Second, fee-for-service payment<br />

encourages providers to deliver the wrong mix of services. In a system with<br />

payment rates for thousands of different services, payment rates for some<br />

services will inevitably end up being set too high relative to the underlying<br />

cost of some services and too low for others, biasing care toward those<br />

services that happen to be particularly profitable, whether or not those<br />

services create the most value for patients. Third, fee-for-service payment<br />

fails to reward providers who improve health outcomes because payment is<br />

completely independent of the outcomes they achieve for their patients.19<br />

The perverse short-run incentives created by fee-for-service payment<br />

may also distort the long-run trajectory of medical technology. Because<br />

of the shortcomings catalogued above, fee-for-service payment tends to<br />

encourage widespread use of resource-intensive new technologies, even if<br />

they generate modest health benefits, while often failing to ensure equally<br />

widespread use of less resource-intensive new technologies that generate<br />

19 While health care professionals have other reasons to deliver high-quality care, including<br />

their concern for their patients’ well-being and their desire to attract and retain patients, the<br />

evidence summarized earlier demonstrates that this was not always sufficient to ensure that all<br />

patients received high-quality care.<br />

Reforming the Health Care System | 249

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!