30.01.2013 Views

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Employment</strong>: <strong>From</strong> <strong>Myths</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Facts</strong><br />

Box 3-6: Linear programming: Another approach <strong>to</strong> assess<br />

the employment effects of trade<br />

Linear programming models are an extension of input-output models that essentially<br />

allow for multiple processes <strong>to</strong> produce the same good. Policy-makers lucky enough <strong>to</strong><br />

have detailed data on options that do not yet exist can add the technological coefficients<br />

<strong>to</strong> the input-output matrix <strong>and</strong> ask a program such as LINDO (or even Excel if the<br />

problem is small enough) for the “best” combination of sec<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> maximize some<br />

objective function.<br />

Dorfman et al. (1958), the classic reference in the field, would use GDP as the welfare<br />

function <strong>to</strong> be optimized. But it may occur <strong>to</strong> an enterprising policy-maker that she could<br />

ask the program <strong>to</strong> maximize employment. She will be sorely disappointed, however,<br />

since the program will almost certainly produce a nonsensical solution. It is obvious why:<br />

employment was maximized when 100 per cent of the labour force was occupied in<br />

agriculture or, for that matter, in hunter-gatherer activities.<br />

Still, linear programming analysis can be highly useful for practical trade analysis in the<br />

h<strong>and</strong>s of skilled analysts <strong>and</strong> a relatively skilled data processing team. They must be<br />

crafted for highly specific problems with well-defined constraints. The real value of the<br />

approach comes not in solving the primal problem, the allocation of labour for example,<br />

but in the duality theorem: the dual variable associated with a constraint that fails <strong>to</strong><br />

bind in the primal is always zero.<br />

Consider an example in which a lengthy list of occupational categories is included in<br />

the employment database. Calculate the primal solution that maximizes some agreedupon<br />

objective function. The dual variable is known as the shadow value because it<br />

measures the change in the objective function, if some small additional amount of the<br />

binding resource could be found. If it turns out that the shadow value of the ith skill<br />

category is zero, then there is no reason <strong>to</strong> design policy <strong>to</strong> increase its supply, at least<br />

in the short run. This idea of complementary slackness, the relationship between the<br />

primal constraint <strong>and</strong> the value of the associated dual variable, is one of the most<br />

profound in economics. It explains why fac<strong>to</strong>rs get the returns they do, their shadow<br />

values, in an economy that obeys the laws of perfect competition. To the extent that the<br />

economy differs from the competitive ideal, some additional constraints would have <strong>to</strong><br />

be built in.<br />

Linear programming has an illustrious his<strong>to</strong>ry since it was first used by the US Army in<br />

its operations research. Its glory has faded somewhat as vastly more sophisticated programs<br />

such as the General Algebraic Modelling System (GAMS) have become available.<br />

This programming language, used extensively in CGE modelling, h<strong>and</strong>les linear programming<br />

as a special case <strong>and</strong> as a result has relegated the method <strong>to</strong> use in problems of<br />

such extreme dimensions that the non-linear counterpart fails.<br />

3.3.4 Social accounting matrices <strong>and</strong> computable general<br />

equilibrium (CGE) models<br />

3.3.4.1 An introduction in<strong>to</strong> CGE modelling<br />

As intimated above, CGE models are computer-based simulations capable of constructing<br />

counterfactual scenarios that have been found <strong>to</strong> be very useful in policy<br />

discussions. 31 A counterfactual is the state of the world in which current policies are<br />

not in force but some others are. The plausibility of the counterfactual depends on:<br />

31 See Ginsburgh <strong>and</strong> Keyzer (1997), Dervis et al. (1982) <strong>and</strong> Taylor (1990) for some general examples<br />

of this literature. Of special interest on closure is Dewatripont <strong>and</strong> Michel (1987).<br />

88

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!