30.01.2013 Views

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Chapter 3: Assessing the impact of trade on employment: Methods of analysis<br />

World Bank economists have estimated global gains as much as US$520 billion<br />

with two-thirds of it going <strong>to</strong> developing countries. In the context of a US$50 trillion<br />

world economy, this is just over 1 per cent, observable, but not game-changing.<br />

Similarly, some 140 million people have escaped poverty due <strong>to</strong> trade liberalization<br />

according <strong>to</strong> World Bank economists. This effect is relatively larger; there are around<br />

1 billion people in poverty worldwide, depending on how poverty is defined. Nothing<br />

in these numbers changes the general view that trade has only a peripheral impact<br />

on employment.<br />

The discussion offered by Ackerman <strong>and</strong> Gallagher (2002) also highlights the<br />

role of data in the debate, weighing in against previous tales about how underlying<br />

SAMs <strong>to</strong> which CGE models had been calibrated were inadvertently switched, but<br />

with no perceptible effect on the outcomes of the simulations! The larger effect of<br />

liberalization observed in the GTAP 5 database seems <strong>to</strong> have diminished indeed.<br />

The GTAP 6 database describes the year 2001 <strong>and</strong> incorporates trade agreements<br />

reached through 2005, including China’s entry in<strong>to</strong> the WTO, the expansion of the<br />

European Union in 2004, <strong>and</strong> the end of the Multi-Fibre Agreement (Anderson et<br />

al., 2005; van der Mensbrugghe, 2007). The more up-<strong>to</strong>-date data incorporate the<br />

gains from previous tariff reductions, of course, but at the same time permit smaller<br />

gains from future reductions. 39<br />

On a more theoretical level, Hammouda <strong>and</strong> Osakwe (2006) note three sources<br />

of weakness in CGE models: the theoretical framework or structure; database availability<br />

<strong>and</strong> accuracy; <strong>and</strong> the distinction between model parameters <strong>and</strong> endogenous<br />

variables. The authors join Taylor <strong>and</strong> von Arnim (2006) in identifying the<br />

Arming<strong>to</strong>n function <strong>and</strong> its estimated elasticities, as a central vulnerability. In this<br />

view, policy recommendations seem <strong>to</strong> hinge on a parameter that cannot be estimated<br />

with great accuracy. 40 All CGE model critics note that strategic considerations,<br />

power relations, regional hegemony <strong>and</strong> other local rigidities are entirely left out<br />

of the model specification. To the extent that these models are guided by the spirit<br />

of the Walrasian general equilibrium system, they miss some of the features central<br />

<strong>to</strong> the development process, such as restricted or entirely absent credit markets,<br />

uncertainty around property own ership <strong>and</strong> title, asymmetric information problems<br />

<strong>and</strong> general coordination issues. Adjustment costs, <strong>to</strong>o, are often left out of the<br />

models. Many of these criticisms can be addressed using agent-based methods, but<br />

that work remains in its infancy (Epstein, 2006).<br />

39 It is important <strong>to</strong> see, however, that tariff changes can happen in both directions, so the model is<br />

still useful in predicting what would happen, hysteresis aside, were some backtracking <strong>to</strong> occur. The<br />

<strong>to</strong>ne of the critics notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing, it is difficult <strong>to</strong> see the relevance of the critique of their CGE<br />

methodology as anything more than the recognition that diminishing returns <strong>to</strong> trade liberalization<br />

are setting in. The World Bank’s LINKAGE model predicted, for example, a gain for developing countries<br />

of US$539 billion in 2003 but by 2005 the impact had fallen <strong>to</strong> US$86 billion. Hertel <strong>and</strong> Keeney<br />

(2005) use the GTAP model <strong>to</strong> estimate the benefits available from removal of all remaining barriers<br />

<strong>to</strong> merch<strong>and</strong>ise trade, some US$84 billion, mostly from the liberalization of agriculture.<br />

40 The desk<strong>to</strong>p CGE elaborated above can certainly be used <strong>to</strong> test this hypothesis. Raise the import<br />

price <strong>and</strong> lower the level of import growth: the model then mimics the presence of an Arming<strong>to</strong>n,<br />

without the computational complexity.<br />

101

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!