30.01.2013 Views

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Employment</strong>: <strong>From</strong> <strong>Myths</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Facts</strong><br />

Table 3.5: Overall welfare gains from removal of all trade barriers in various<br />

CGE models<br />

Study GTAP Sec<strong>to</strong>rs/ Static/ Returns Competition: Welfare gains<br />

data regions dynamic <strong>to</strong> scale perfect (PC) or ($US bn)<br />

monopolistic<br />

(MC)<br />

OECD1 5 10/10 Static CRS PC 173.60<br />

Cline2 5 22/25 Static CRS PC 227.80<br />

Anderson et al. 3 4 4/19 Static CRS PC 263.50<br />

Anderson et al. 4 6 25/27 Dynamic CRS PC 264.80<br />

Francois et al. 5 5 17/16 Dynamic Ag: CRS Ag: PC 367.30<br />

Mfg: IRS Mfg: MC<br />

Brown et al. 6 4 18/20 Dynamic Ag: CRS Ag: PC 2154.50<br />

Mfg: IRS Mfg: MC<br />

Source: Piermartini <strong>and</strong> Teh (2005).<br />

Notes: 1. OECD (2003); 2. Cline (2004); 3. Anderson et al. (2001); 4. Anderson et al. (2005);<br />

5. Francois et al. (2003); 6. Brown et al. (2003).<br />

the size <strong>and</strong> even direction of the results. There are fundamental differences between<br />

economies with surplus labour <strong>and</strong> those without (cyclical fluctuations notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing)<br />

<strong>and</strong> it is this difference rather than the specific details of the labour market<br />

that must be pinned down before a model is ready for use in policy discussions.<br />

Table 3.5 shows a summary of model structures <strong>and</strong> results for a number of<br />

models surveyed recently. As an example of how results from CGE models may vary<br />

with the database, structure of the models <strong>and</strong> the exact simulations undertaken,<br />

consider the information in table 3.5. The results of the studies in the table are presented<br />

as the <strong>to</strong>tal overall welfare gains from the removal of trade barriers, in the<br />

right-most column. <strong>From</strong> the table, the estimated gains range from a low of US$173.6<br />

billion <strong>to</strong> a high of US$2,154.5 billion, with four of the six studies in a narrower<br />

range from US$227.8 billion <strong>to</strong> US$367.3 billion. The size of the gains increases as<br />

the models move from static <strong>to</strong> dynamic. Note also the assumptions about competition<br />

are altered in some studies <strong>to</strong> allow for imperfect competition, in the form of<br />

monopolistic competition. The effect is restricted <strong>to</strong> the manufacturing sec<strong>to</strong>r alone.<br />

The table shows that structure makes a difference <strong>and</strong> this certainly irks some<br />

observers. Ackerman <strong>and</strong> Gallagher (2002) note that “the results of these models are<br />

typically reported as if they were hard, objective facts, providing unambiguous numerical<br />

measures of the value of liberalization”. This could be a complaint made<br />

only by those with the most fleeting association with economic models of any kind<br />

<strong>and</strong> their use in modern political discourse. While it is possible <strong>to</strong> imagine that<br />

model results are sometimes presented in this way, there is certainly no shortage of<br />

98

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!