30.01.2013 Views

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Chapter 3: Assessing the impact of trade on employment: Methods of analysis<br />

Yet foreign products are not always able <strong>to</strong> satisfy consumers’ preferences in<br />

precisely the same way that domestic production does. The point is that it is not<br />

really the same good for all consumers <strong>and</strong> so some are willing <strong>to</strong> pay the premium<br />

<strong>to</strong> “buy local” <strong>to</strong> keep domestic production viable. The imported <strong>and</strong> the locally<br />

produced goods are considered imperfect substitutes in this case, <strong>and</strong> two different<br />

prices will co-exist for the “same” good. The employment impact of tariff reductions<br />

will then crucially depend on the level of the so-called elasticity of substitution between<br />

imported <strong>and</strong> locally produced goods. This elasticity is called the “Arming<strong>to</strong>n<br />

elasticity” <strong>and</strong> is an important element of most trade-related simulation exercises.<br />

Box 3-2 provides details using the Arming<strong>to</strong>n elasticity <strong>to</strong> estimate the effect of<br />

cheaper imports on domestic employment.<br />

The greater the consumer attachment <strong>to</strong> domestic goods vis-à-vis their foreign<br />

rivals, the smaller the σ <strong>and</strong> the less job loss will occur. 18 Figure 3.1 reflects simulation<br />

results of the employment response <strong>to</strong> changes in foreign prices. The horizontal axis<br />

depicts foreign prices relative <strong>to</strong> domestic prices. If foreign goods are cheaper than<br />

domestically produced goods, the relative price on the horizontal axis is smaller<br />

than one. The vertical axis shows employment losses generated by reductions in foreign<br />

prices. The three curves depicted in the chart reflect employment losses<br />

corresponding <strong>to</strong> different levels of import substitution. The higher the level of substitution,<br />

i.e. the larger the Arming<strong>to</strong>n elasticity σ, the larger the employment losses<br />

resulting from import competition.<br />

Many comparative static exercises could be undertaken with this simple model:<br />

the jobs response also depends on the initial share of imports <strong>and</strong> the supply elasticity,<br />

μ, both of which can be changed. For σ > ε , job loss increases with the initial share<br />

of imports <strong>and</strong> decreases with the supply elasticity. Note the elephant in the room<br />

here: while there is job loss, the consumer price always decreases, leaving consumers<br />

better off than if trade barriers had not been lowered. This is the classic trade-off,<br />

captured in table 3.1 above, <strong>and</strong> now in this desk<strong>to</strong>p CPE model.<br />

Although partial equilibrium approaches have most frequently been used <strong>to</strong><br />

assess the employment effects of increased imports, they can also be used <strong>to</strong> evaluate<br />

the employment effects of increased export opportunities. Not surprisingly, a focus<br />

on exporting sec<strong>to</strong>rs would tend <strong>to</strong> give an overly-optimistic picture of the employment<br />

effects of trade. As in the case of imports, the question of substitution between<br />

trade <strong>and</strong> domestically produced goods also arises in the case of exports. As noted<br />

in Sadoulet <strong>and</strong> de Janvry (1995), a bilateral choice model can be set up <strong>to</strong> extend<br />

<strong>to</strong> producers as well as consumers, as illustrated above. Exports in a world with competitive<br />

exchange rates may be very attractive for producers, but foreign markets<br />

also bear risks, many of which are absent in domestic markets. Quality control issues,<br />

forward markets for export earnings <strong>and</strong> other incentives may entice domestic producers<br />

<strong>to</strong> “sell local” when models with perfect substitution would suggest otherwise.<br />

18 Note that according <strong>to</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard theory there is nothing inefficient whatsoever about this<br />

attachment.<br />

77

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!